×

Shapley facility location games. (English) Zbl 1405.91014

Devanur, Nikhil R. (ed.) et al., Web and internet economics. 13th international conference, WINE 2017, Bangalore, India, December 17–20, 2017. Proceedings. Cham: Springer (ISBN 978-3-319-71923-8/pbk; 978-3-319-71924-5/ebook). Lecture Notes in Computer Science 10660, 58-73 (2017).
Summary: Facility location games have been a topic of major interest in economics, operations research and computer science, starting from the seminal work by Hotelling. Spatial facility location models have successfully predicted the outcome of competition in a variety of scenarios. In a typical facility location game, users/customers/voters are mapped to a metric space representing their preferences, and each player picks a point (facility) in that space. In most facility location games considered in the literature, users are assumed to act deterministically: given the facilities chosen by the players, users are attracted to their nearest facility. This paper introduces facility location games with probabilistic attraction, dubbed Shapley facility location games, due to a surprising connection to the Shapley value. The specific attraction function we adopt in this model is aligned with the recent findings of the behavioral economics literature on choice prediction. Given this model, our first main result is that Shapley facility location games are potential games; hence, they possess pure Nash equilibrium. Moreover, the latter is true for any compact user space, any user distribution over that space, and any number of players. Note that this is in sharp contrast to Hotelling facility location games. In our second main result we show that under the assumption that players can compute an approximate best response, approximate equilibrium profiles can be learned efficiently by the players via dynamics. Our third main result is a bound on the price of anarchy of this class of games, as well as showing the bound is tight. Ultimately, we show that player payoffs coincide with their Shapley value in a coalition game, where coalition gains are the social welfare of the users.
For the entire collection see [Zbl 1381.68004].

MSC:

91A12 Cooperative games
91B72 Spatial models in economics

References:

[1] Ahn, HK; Cheng, SW; Cheong, O.; Golin, M.; Van Oostrum, R., Competitive facility location: the voronoi game, Theoret. Comput. Sci., 310, 1, 457-467, 2004 · Zbl 1098.91003 · doi:10.1016/j.tcs.2003.09.004
[2] Awerbuch, B., Azar, Y., Epstein, A., Mirrokni, V.S., Skopalik, A.: Fast convergence to nearly optimal solutions in potential games. In: Proceedings of the 9th ACM Conference on Electronic Commerce, pp. 264-273. ACM (2008)
[3] Barron, G.; Erev, I., Small feedback-based decisions and their limited correspondence to description-based decisions, J. Behav. Decis. Making, 16, 3, 215-233, 2003 · doi:10.1002/bdm.443
[4] Ben-Basat, R., Tennenholtz, M., Kurland, O.: The probability ranking principle is not optimal in adversarial retrieval settings. In: Proceedings of the 2015 International Conference on the Theory of Information Retrieval, ICTIR 2015, Northampton, Massachusetts, USA, 27-30 September 2015, pp. 51-60 (2015)
[5] Brenner, S.: Location (hotelling) games and applications. In: Wiley Encyclopedia of Operations Research and Management Science (2011)
[6] Cheong, O.; Har-Peled, S.; Linial, N.; Matousek, J., The one-round voronoi game, Discret. Comput. Geom., 31, 1, 125-138, 2004 · Zbl 1079.91010 · doi:10.1007/s00454-003-2951-4
[7] Chien, S., Sinclair, A.: Convergence to approximate nash equilibria in congestion games. In: Proceedings of the Eighteenth Annual ACM-SIAM Symposium on Discrete Algorithms, pp. 169-178. Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics (2007) · Zbl 1303.91018
[8] Dubey, P., On the uniqueness of the shapley value, Int. J. Game Theory, 4, 3, 131-139, 1975 · Zbl 0352.90085 · doi:10.1007/BF01780630
[9] Eaton, BC; Lipsey, RG, The principle of minimum differentiation reconsidered: some new developments in the theory of spatial competition, Rev. Econ. Stud., 42, 1, 27-49, 1975 · Zbl 0294.90003 · doi:10.2307/2296817
[10] Erev, I., Ert, E., Plonsky, O.: From anomalies to forecasts: a choice prediction competition for decisions under risk and ambiguity. Technical report, Mimeo, pp. 1-56 (2015)
[11] Erev, I.; Ert, E.; Roth, AE; Haruvy, E.; Herzog, SM; Hau, R.; Hertwig, R.; Stewart, T.; West, R.; Lebiere, C., A choice prediction competition: choices from experience and from description, J. Behav. Decis. Making, 23, 1, 15-47, 2010 · doi:10.1002/bdm.683
[12] Fekete, SP; Meijer, H., The one-round voronoi game replayed, Comput. Geom., 30, 2, 81-94, 2005 · Zbl 1068.65035 · doi:10.1016/j.comgeo.2004.05.005
[13] Feldman, M., Fiat, A., Obraztsova, S.: Variations on the hotelling-downs model. In: Thirtieth AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence (2016)
[14] Hotelling, H., Stability in competition, Econ. J., 39, 153, 41-57, 1929 · doi:10.2307/2224214
[15] Izsak, P., Raiber, F., Kurland, O., Tennenholtz, M.: The search duel: a response to a strong ranker. In: Proceedings of the 37th International ACM SIGIR Conference on Research and Development in Information Retrieval, pp. 919-922. ACM (2014)
[16] Kahneman, D.; Tversky, A., Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk, Econometrica, 47, 2, 263-292, 1979 · Zbl 0411.90012 · doi:10.2307/1914185
[17] Koutsoupias, E.; Papadimitriou, C.; Meinel, C.; Tison, S., Worst-case equilibria, STACS 99, 404-413, 1999, Heidelberg: Springer, Heidelberg · Zbl 1099.91501 · doi:10.1007/3-540-49116-3_38
[18] McFadden, D., Econometric models for probabilistic choice among products, J. Bus., 53, 3, S13-S29, 1980 · doi:10.1086/296093
[19] Monderer, D.; Shapley, LS, Potential games, Games Econ. Behav., 14, 1, 124-143, 1996 · Zbl 0862.90137 · doi:10.1006/game.1996.0044
[20] Nisan, N.; Roughgarden, T.; Tardos, E.; Vazirani, V., Algorithmic Game Theory, 2007, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge · Zbl 1130.91005 · doi:10.1017/CBO9780511800481
[21] Plonsky, O., Erev, I., Hazan, T., Tennenholtz, M.: Psychological forest: Predicting human behavior (2017)
[22] Procaccia, A., Tennenholtz, M.: Approximate mechanism design without money. In: EC-09 (2009)
[23] Rosenthal, RW, A class of games possessing pure-strategy nash equilibria, Int. J. Game Theory, 2, 1, 65-67, 1973 · Zbl 0259.90059 · doi:10.1007/BF01737559
[24] Roughgarden, T.: Intrinsic robustness of the price of anarchy. In: Proceedings of the Forty-First Annual ACM Symposium on Theory of Computing, pp. 513-522. ACM (2009) · Zbl 1304.91019
[25] Schummer, J., Vohra, R.: Mechanism design without money. In: Nisan, N., Roughgarden, T., Tardos, E., Vazirani, V.V. (eds.) Algorithmic Game Theory, pp. 110-130. Cambridge University Press (2007)
[26] Shaked, A., Non-existence of equilibrium for the two-dimensional three-firms location problem, Rev. Econ. Stud., 42, 1, 51-56, 1975 · Zbl 0295.90010 · doi:10.2307/2296818
[27] Shaked, A., Existence and computation of mixed strategy Nash equilibrium for 3-firms location problem, J. Ind. Econ., 31, 1-2, 93-96, 1982 · doi:10.2307/2098006
[28] Shapley, L.S.: A value for n-person games. Techncial report, DTIC Document (1952)
[29] Shen, W., Wang, Z.: Hotelling-downs model with limited attraction. In: Proceedings of the 16th Conference on Autonomous Agents and MultiAgent Systems, pp. 660-668. International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems (2017)
[30] Simon, HA, Rational choice and the structure of the environment, Psychol. Rev., 63, 2, 129, 1956 · doi:10.1037/h0042769
This reference list is based on information provided by the publisher or from digital mathematics libraries. Its items are heuristically matched to zbMATH identifiers and may contain data conversion errors. In some cases that data have been complemented/enhanced by data from zbMATH Open. This attempts to reflect the references listed in the original paper as accurately as possible without claiming completeness or a perfect matching.