×

Construction of voting situations concordant with ranking patterns. (English) Zbl 1519.91097

This paper considers the context of voting theory based on a family of possible elections with a fixed set of voters and a fixed set of potential candidates. Attention is focused on the concept of voting situation \(q\)-concordant with a ranking pattern. The concept of ranking pattern \(p\)-concordant with probability models for non-negative random variables is also explored. Results concerning with existence and construction and with cardinalities of the related voters’ populations are obtained. New proofs are obtained of the possibility of observing any arbitrary set of elections’ outcomes. Information about the number of voters needed to construct concordant voting situations is provided. The analysis distinguishes between the two cases of weak and strict ranking patterns. For strict ranking patterns, the solutions can be presented in closed forms.

MSC:

91B12 Voting theory
91B14 Social choice
60E15 Inequalities; stochastic orderings

References:

[1] Alon, N., Voting paradoxes and digraphs realizations, Adv. Appl. Math., 29, 1, 126-135 (2002) · Zbl 1020.91012 · doi:10.1016/S0196-8858(02)00007-6
[2] De Santis, E., Ranking graphs through hitting times of Markov chains, Random Struct. Algorithms, 59, 189-203 (2021) · Zbl 1523.60125 · doi:10.1002/rsa.20998
[3] De Santis, E.; Spizzichino, F., First occurrence of a word among the elements of a finite dictionary in random sequences of letters, Electron. J. Probab., 17, 25, 9 (2012) · Zbl 1245.60010
[4] De Santis, E.; Spizzichino, F., Construction of aggregation paradoxes through load-sharing models, Adv. Appl. Probab., 55, 1, 223-244 (2023) · Zbl 1523.60141 · doi:10.1017/apr.2022.17
[5] De Santis, E.; Malinovsky, Y.; Spizzichino, F., Stochastic precedence and minima among dependent variables, Methodol. Comput. Appl. Probab., 23, 187-205 (2021) · Zbl 1480.60270 · doi:10.1007/s11009-020-09772-3
[6] Erdos, P.; Moser, L., On the representation of directed graphs as unions of orderings, Magyar Tud. Akad. Mat. Kutató Int. Közl., 9, 125-132 (1964) · Zbl 0136.44901
[7] Fishburn, PC, Inverted orders for monotone scoring rules, Discrete Appl. Math., 3, 1, 27-36 (1981) · Zbl 0451.90010 · doi:10.1016/0166-218X(81)90025-1
[8] Gehrlein, WV; Lepelley, D., Elections, Voting Rules and Paradoxical Outcomes. Studies in Choice and Welfare (2017), Cham: Springer, Cham · Zbl 1429.91003 · doi:10.1007/978-3-319-64659-6
[9] Guibas, LJ; Odlyzko, AM, String overlaps, pattern matching, and nontransitive games, J. Comb. Theory Ser. A, 30, 2, 183-208 (1981) · Zbl 0454.68109 · doi:10.1016/0097-3165(81)90005-4
[10] Hazla, J.; Mossel, E.; Ross, N.; Zheng, G., The probability of intransitivity in dice and close elections, Probab. Theory Relat. Fields, 178, 951-1009 (2020) · Zbl 1468.60014 · doi:10.1007/s00440-020-00994-7
[11] Kalai, G., Social indeterminacy, Econometrica, 72, 5, 1565-1581 (2004) · Zbl 1141.91373 · doi:10.1111/j.1468-0262.2004.00543.x
[12] Klamler, C., Borda and Condorcet: some distance results, Theory Decis., 59, 97-109 (2005) · Zbl 1119.91030 · doi:10.1007/s11238-005-5459-y
[13] Mala, J., On \(\lambda \)-majority voting paradoxes, Math. Soc. Sci., 37, 1, 39-44 (1999) · Zbl 0944.91017 · doi:10.1016/S0165-4896(98)00012-2
[14] McGarvey, DC, A theorem on the construction of voting paradoxes, Econometrica, 21, 608-610 (1953) · doi:10.2307/1907926
[15] Montes, I.; Rademaker, M.; Perez-Fernandez, R.; De Baets, B., A correspondence between voting procedures and stochastic orderings, Eur. J. Oper. Res., 285, 977-987 (2020) · Zbl 1443.91128 · doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2020.02.038
[16] Nurmi, H., Voting Paradoxes and How to Deal with Them (1999), Berlin: Springer, Berlin · Zbl 0943.91030 · doi:10.1007/978-3-662-03782-9
[17] Perez-Fernandez, R.; De Baets, B., The superdominance relation, the positional winner, and more missing links between Borda and Condorcet, J. Theor. Politics, 31, 46-65 (2019) · doi:10.1177/0951629818809417
[18] Saari, DG, A dictionary for voting paradoxes, J. Econ. Theory, 48, 2, 443-475 (1989) · Zbl 0672.90010 · doi:10.1016/0022-0531(89)90037-9
[19] Saari, DG, A chaotic exploration of aggregation paradoxes, SIAM Rev., 37, 1, 37-52 (1995) · Zbl 0834.90012 · doi:10.1137/1037002
[20] Saari, DG; Batchelder, WH; Colonius, H.; Dzhafarov, EN, Discovering aggregation properties via voting, New Handbook of Mathematical Psychology, 271-321 (2018), Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge · Zbl 1394.91002
[21] Saari, DG, Mathematics Motivated by the Social and Behavioral Sciences (2018), Philadelphia: SIAM, Philadelphia · Zbl 1390.91008 · doi:10.1137/1.9781611975185
[22] Shaked, M.; Shanthikumar, JG, Stochastic Orders and Their Applications. Probability and Mathematical Statistics (1994), Boston: Academic Press, Inc., Boston · Zbl 0806.62009
[23] Shaked, M.; Shanthikumar, JG, Multivariate conditional hazard rate functions: an overview, Appl. Stoch. Models Bus. Ind., 31, 3, 285-296 (2015) · Zbl 07883222 · doi:10.1002/asmb.2020
[24] Spizzichino, F., Reliability, signature, and relative quality functions of systems under time-homogeneous load-sharing models, Appl. Stoch. Models Bus. Ind., 35, 2, 158-176 (2019) · Zbl 1431.90055 · doi:10.1002/asmb.2397
[25] Stearns, R., The voting problem, Am. Math. Mon., 66, 761-763 (1959) · Zbl 0090.25101 · doi:10.1080/00029890.1959.11989405
[26] Van Newenhizen, J., The Borda method is most likely to respect the Condorcet principle, Econ. Theory, 2, 69-83 (1992) · Zbl 0810.90023 · doi:10.1007/BF01213253
This reference list is based on information provided by the publisher or from digital mathematics libraries. Its items are heuristically matched to zbMATH identifiers and may contain data conversion errors. In some cases that data have been complemented/enhanced by data from zbMATH Open. This attempts to reflect the references listed in the original paper as accurately as possible without claiming completeness or a perfect matching.