×

QTest 2.1: quantitative testing of theories of binary choice using Bayesian inference. (English) Zbl 1426.91080

Summary: This stand-alone tutorial gives an introduction to the QTest 2.1 public domain software package for the specification and statistical analysis of certain order-constrained probabilistic choice models. Like its predecessors, QTest 2.1 allows a user to specify a variety of probabilistic models of binary responses and to carry out state-of-the-art frequentist order-constrained hypothesis tests within a graphical user interface (GUI). QTest 2.1 automatizes the mathematical characterization of so-called “random preference models”, adds some parallel computing capabilities, and, most importantly, adds tools for Bayesian inference and model selection. In this tutorial, we provide an in-depth introduction to the Bayesian features: We review order-constrained Bayesian \(p\)-values, DIC and Bayes factors, building on the data, models, and prior QTest based frequentist data analyses of an earlier (frequentist) tutorial by M. Regenwetter et al. [“QTest: Quantitative testing of theories of binary choice”, Decis. 1, 2–34 (2014; doi:10.1037/dec0000007)].

MSC:

91B06 Decision theory
62P20 Applications of statistics to economics
62P15 Applications of statistics to psychology

Software:

QTest
Full Text: DOI

References:

[1] Akaike, H., A new look at the statistical identification model, IEEE Transactions of Automation Control, 19, 716-723 (1974) · Zbl 0314.62039
[4] Block, H. D.; Marschak, J., Random orderings and stochastic theories of responses, (Olkin, I.; Ghurye, S.; Hoeffding, H.; Madow, W.; Mann, H., Contributions to probability and statistics (1960), Stanford University Press: Stanford University Press Stanford), 97-132 · Zbl 0096.12104
[5] Bolotashvili, G.; Kovalev, M.; Girlich, E., New facets of the linear ordering polytope, SIAM Journal of Discrete Mathematics, 12, 326-336 (1999) · Zbl 0966.90085
[6] Casella, G.; George, E. I., Explaining the Gibbs sampler, The American Statistician, 46, 167-174 (1992)
[8] Cavagnaro, D. R.; Davis-Stober, C. P., Transitive in our preferences, but transitive in different ways: an analysis of choice variability, Decision, 1, 102-122 (2014)
[9] Cavagnaro, D. R.; Davis-Stober, C. P., A model-based test for treatment effects with probabilistic classifications, Psychological Methods, 23, 672-689 (2018)
[11] Cha, Y.-C.; Choi, M.; Guo, Y.; Regenwetter, M.; Zwilling, C., Reply: Birnbaum’s (2012) statistical tests of independence have unknown Type I error rates and do not replicate within participant, Judgment and Decision Making, 8, 55-73 (2013)
[13] Davis-Stober, C. P., Analysis of multinomial models under inequality constraints: applications to measurement theory, Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 53, 1-13 (2009) · Zbl 1176.91140
[14] Davis-Stober, C. P., A lexicographic semiorder polytope and probabilistic representations of choice, Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 56, 86-94 (2012) · Zbl 1245.91020
[15] Davis-Stober, C. P.; Brown, N.; Park, S.; Regenwetter, M., Recasting a biologically motivated computational model within a Fechnerian and random utility framework, Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 77, 156-164 (2017) · Zbl 1396.91661
[16] Davis-Stober, C. P.; Park, S.; Brown, N.; Regenwetter, M., Reported violations of rationality may be aggregation artifacts, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 113, 33, E4761-E4763 (2016)
[17] Doignon, J.-P.; Fiorini, S., Facets of the weak order polytope derived from the induced partition projection, SIAM Journal of Discrete Mathematics, 15, 112-121 (2002) · Zbl 1009.52024
[18] Doignon, J.-P.; Fiorini, S., The approval-voting polytope: combinatorial interpretation of the facets, Mathématiques, Informatique et Sciences Humaines, 161, 29-39 (2003)
[19] Doignon, J.-P.; Fiorini, S., The facets and the symmetries of the approval-voting polytope, Journal of Combinatorial Theory. Series B, 92, 1-12 (2004) · Zbl 1060.52005
[20] Doignon, J.-P.; Fiorini, S.; Joret, G., Facets of the linear ordering polytope: a unification for the fence family through weighted graphs, Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 50, 251-262 (2006) · Zbl 1096.05050
[21] Doignon, J.-P.; Fiorini, S.; Joret, G., Erratum to: “Facets of the linear ordering polytope: a unification for the fence family through weighted graphs:” (vol 50, pg 251, 2006), Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 51, 341 (2007) · Zbl 1096.05050
[22] Fishburn, P. C., Signed orders and power set extensions, Journal of Economic Theory, 56, 1-19 (1992) · Zbl 0764.90009
[23] Fishburn, P. C.; Falmagne, J.-C., Binary choice probabilities and rankings, Economics Letters, 31, 113-117 (1989) · Zbl 1375.91053
[25] Grötschel, M.; Jünger, M.; Reinelt, G., Facets of the linear ordering polytope, Mathematical Programming, 33, 43-60 (1985) · Zbl 0577.05035
[26] Guo, Y.; Regenwetter, M., Quantitative tests of the Preceived Relative Argument Model: Comment on Loomes (2010), Psychological Review, 121, 696-705 (2014)
[27] He, L.; Golman, R.; Bhatia, S., Variable time preference, Cognitive Psychology 111, 53-79 (2019)
[28] Iverson, G. J.; Falmagne, J.-C., Statistical issues in measurement, Mathematical Social Sciences, 10, 131-153 (1985) · Zbl 0613.62145
[29] Kass, R. E.; Raftery, A. E., Bayes factors, Journal of the American Statistical Association, 90, 773-795 (1995) · Zbl 0846.62028
[30] Kerman, J., Neutral noninformative and informative conjugate beta and gamma prior distributions, Electronic Journal of Statistics, 5, 1450-1470 (2011) · Zbl 1271.62045
[31] Klugkist, I.; Hoijtink, H., The Bayes factor for inequality and about equality constrained models, Computational Statistics & Data Analysis, 51, 6367-6379 (2007) · Zbl 1445.62049
[32] Koppen, M., Random utility representation of binary choice probabilities: critical graphs yielding critical necessary conditions, Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 39, 21-39 (1995) · Zbl 0897.92045
[33] Loomes, G.; Sugden, R., Incorporating a stochastic element into decision theories, European Economic Review, 39, 641-648 (1995)
[34] Luce, R. D.; Suppes, P., Preference, utility and subjective probability, (Luce, R. D.; Bush, R. R.; Galanter, E., Handbook of mathematical psychology, Vol. III (1965), Wiley: Wiley New York), 249-410
[35] Marley, A.; Regenwetter, M., Choice, preference, and utility: probabilistic and deterministic representations, (Batchelder, W.; Colonius, H.; Dzhafarov, E.; Myung, I., New handbook of mathematical psychology: Volume 1, foundations and methodology (2017), Cambridge University Press)
[36] McCausland, W. J.; Marley, A., Prior distributions for random choice structures, Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 57, 78-93 (2013) · Zbl 1283.91041
[37] McCullagh, P.; Nelder, J., Generalized linear models (1989), CRC · Zbl 0744.62098
[38] Myung, J.; Karabatsos, G.; Iverson, G. J., A Bayesian approach to testing decision making axioms, Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 49, 205-225 (2005) · Zbl 1104.91016
[39] Regenwetter, M.; Cavagnaro, D., Tutorial on removing the shackles of regression analysis: How to stay true to your theory of binary response probabilities, Psychological Methods, 24, 2, 135-152 (2019)
[40] Regenwetter, M.; Cavagnaro, D.; Popova, A.; Guo, Y.; Zwilling, C.; Lim, S.; Stevens, J., Heterogeneity and parsimony in intertemporal choice, Decision, 5, 63-94 (2018)
[41] Regenwetter, M.; Dana, J.; Davis-Stober, C. P., Testing transitivity of preferences on two-alternative forced choice data, Frontiers in Quantitative Psychology and Measurement, 1 (2010), Article 148
[42] Regenwetter, M.; Dana, J.; Davis-Stober, C. P., Transitivity of preferences, Psychological Review, 118, 42-56 (2011)
[43] Regenwetter, M.; Dana, J.; Davis-Stober, C. P.; Guo, Y., Parsimonious testing of transitive or intransitive preferences: Reply to Birnbaum (2011), Psychological Review, 118, 684-688 (2011)
[44] Regenwetter, M.; Davis-Stober, C. P., There are many models of transitive preference: a tutorial review and current perspective, (Decision modeling and behavior in uncertain and complex environments (2008), Springer-Verlag), 99-124 · Zbl 1386.91068
[45] Regenwetter, M.; Davis-Stober, C. P., Ternary paired comparisons induced by semi- or interval order preferences, (Dzhafarov, E.; Perry, L., Descriptive and normative approaches to human behavior. Descriptive and normative approaches to human behavior, Advanced Series on Mathematical Psychology, Vol. 3 (2011), World Scientific), 225-248 · Zbl 1320.91049
[46] Regenwetter, M.; Davis-Stober, C. P., Behavioral variability of choices versus structural inconsistency of preferences, Psychological Review, 119, 408-416 (2012)
[47] Regenwetter, M.; Davis-Stober, C. P., The role of independence and stationarity in probabilistic models of binary choice, Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 31, 100-114 (2017)
[48] Regenwetter, M.; Davis-Stober, C. P.; Lim, S. H.; Guo, Y.; Popova, A.; Zwilling, C.; Cha, Y.-C.; Messner, W., Qtest: Quantitative testing of theories of binary choice, Decision, 1, 2-34 (2014)
[49] Regenwetter, M.; Robinson, M. M., The construct-behavior gap in behavioral decision research: a challenge beyond replicability, Psychological Review, 124, 533-550 (2017)
[50] Regenwetter, M., & Robinson, M. M. (2019). Nuisance or substance? Leveraging heterogeneity of preference. Manuscript (submitted for publication).; Regenwetter, M., & Robinson, M. M. (2019). Nuisance or substance? Leveraging heterogeneity of preference. Manuscript (submitted for publication).
[51] Rieskamp, J.; Busemeyer, J.; Mellers, B., Extending the bounds of rationality: evidence and theories of preferential choice, Journal of Economic Literature, 44, 631-661 (2006)
[52] Robert, C. P.; Casella, G., Convergence monitoring and adaptation for MCMC algorithms, (Introducing Monte Carlo methods with R. Use R (2010), Springer: Springer New York, NY) · Zbl 1196.65025
[53] Silvapulle, M. J.; Sen, P. K., Constrained statistical inference: inequality, order, and shape restrictions (2005), John Wiley & Sons: John Wiley & Sons New York · Zbl 1077.62019
[54] Spiegelhalter, D. J.; Best, N. G.; Carlin, B. P.; Van Der Linde, A., Bayesian measures of model complexity and fit, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series B. Statistical Methodology, 64, 583-639 (2002) · Zbl 1067.62010
[55] Stephan, K. E.; Penny, W. D.; Daunizeau, J.; Moran, R. J.; Friston, K. J., Bayesian model selection for group studies, Neuroimage, 46, 1004-1017 (2009)
[56] Stott, H., Cumulative prospect theory’s functional menagerie, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 32, 101-130 (2006) · Zbl 1281.91072
[57] Suck, R., Geometric and combinatorial properties of the polytope of binary choice probabilities, Mathematical Social Sciences, 23, 81-102 (1992) · Zbl 0751.90006
[58] Tierney, L., Markov chains for exploring posterior distributions, The Annals of Statistics 22, 1701-1728 (1994) · Zbl 0829.62080
[59] Tsetsos, K.; Moran, R.; Moreland, J.; Chater, N.; Usher, M.; Summerfield, C., Economic irrationality is optimal during noisy decision making, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 113, 3102-3107 (2016)
[60] Tuyl, F.; Gerlach, R.; Mengersen, K., Posterior predictive arguments in favor of the Bayes-Laplace prior as the consensus prior for binomial and multinomial parameters, Bayesian Analysis, 4, 151-158 (2009) · Zbl 1330.62156
[61] Tversky, A., Intransitivity of preferences, Psychological Review, 76, 31-48 (1969)
[62] Tversky, A.; Kahneman, D., Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, 297-323 (1992) · Zbl 0775.90106
This reference list is based on information provided by the publisher or from digital mathematics libraries. Its items are heuristically matched to zbMATH identifiers and may contain data conversion errors. In some cases that data have been complemented/enhanced by data from zbMATH Open. This attempts to reflect the references listed in the original paper as accurately as possible without claiming completeness or a perfect matching.