×

Demand heterogeneity in insurance markets: implications for equity and efficiency. (English) Zbl 1396.91303

Summary: In many markets insurers are barred from price discrimination based on consumer characteristics like age, gender, and medical history. In this paper, I build on a recent literature to show why such policies are inefficient if consumers differ in their willingness-to-pay for insurance conditional on the insured losses they generate. Using administrative claims data, I then show that this type of demand heterogeneity is empirically relevant in a consumer health plan setting. Younger and older consumers and men and women reveal strikingly different demand for health insurance, conditional on their objective medical spending risk. This implies that these groups must face different prices so as to sort themselves efficiently across insurance contracts. The theoretical and empirical analysis highlights a fundamental trade-off between equity and efficiency that is unique to selection markets.

MSC:

91B30 Risk theory, insurance (MSC2010)
91B42 Consumer behavior, demand theory
Full Text: DOI

References:

[1] Abaluck, J. and J.Gruber (2011), “Choice inconsistencies among the elderly: Evidence from plan choice in the medicare part d program.” American Economic Review, 101, 1180-1210.
[2] Akerlof, G. A. (1970), “The market for ‘lemons’: Quality uncertainty and the market mechanism.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84 (3), 488-500.
[3] Angrist, J. D. and J.‐S.Pischke (2008), Mostly Harmless Econometrics: An Empiricist’s Companion. Princeton University Press.
[4] Breyer, F., M. K.Bundorf, and M. V.Pauly (2011), “Health care spending risk, health insurance, and payment to health plans.” In Handbook of Health Economics, Vol. 2, 691-762.
[5] Brown, J., M.Duggan, I.Kuziemko, and W.Woolston (2014), “How does risk selection respond to risk adjustment? New evidence from the medicare advantage program.” American Economic Review, 104 (10), 3335-3364.
[6] Bundorf, M. K., J.Levin, and N.Mahoney (2012), “Pricing and welfare in health plan choice.” American Economic Review, 102 (7), 3214-3248.
[7] Carlin, C. and R.Town (2008), “Adverse selection, welfare and optimal pricing of employer‐sponsored health plans.” Report, University of Minnesota.
[8] Chiappori, P.‐A. and B.Salanie (2000), “Testing for asymmetric information in insurance markets.” Journal of Political Economy, 108 (1), 56-78.
[9] Cohen, A. and L.Einav (2007), “Estimating risk preferences from deductible choice.” American Economic Review, 97 (3), 745-788.
[10] Cutler, D. M., A.Finkelstein, and K.McGarry (2008), “Preference heterogeneity and insurance markets: Explaining a puzzle of insurance.” American Economic Review, 98 (2), 157-162.
[11] Cutler, D. M. and S. J.Reber (1998), “Paying for health insurance: The trade‐off between competition and adverse selection.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113 (2), 433-466.
[12] Einav, L., A.Finkelstein, and M. R.Cullen (2010), “Estimating welfare in insurance markets using variation in prices.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125 (3), 877-921.
[13] Einav, L., A.Finkelstein, and J.Levin (2010), “Beyond testing: Empirical models of insurance markets.” Annual Review of Economics, 2 (1), 311-336.
[14] Einav, L. and A.Finkelstein (2011), “Selection in insurance markets: Theory and empirics in pictures.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25 (1), 115-138.
[15] Einav, L., A.Finkelstein, S. P.Ryan, P.Schrimpf, and M. R.Cullen (2013), “Selection on moral hazard in health insurance.” American Economic Review, 103 (1), 178-219.
[16] Ericson, K. M. M. and A.Starc (2015), “Pricing regulation and imperfect competition on the Massachusetts health insurance exchange.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 97 (3), 667-682.
[17] Fang, H., M. P.Keane, and D.Silverman (2008), “Sources of advantageous selection: Evidence from the medigap insurance market.” Journal of Political Economy, 116 (2), 303-350.
[18] Feldman, R. and B.Dowd (2000), “Risk segmentation: Goal or problem?” Journal of Health Economics, 19 (4), 499-512.
[19] Finkelstein, A. and K.McGarry (2006), “Multiple dimensions of private information: Evidence from the long‐term care insurance market.” American Economic Review, 96 (4), 938-958.
[20] Finkelstein, A. and J.Poterba (2004), “Adverse selection in insurance markets: Policyholder evidence from the UK annuity market.” Journal of Political Economy, 112 (1), 183-208.
[21] Finkelstein, A., J.Poterba, and C.Rothschild (2009), “Redistribution by insurance market regulation: Analyzing a ban on gender‐based retirement annuities.” Journal of Financial Economics, 91 (1), 38-58.
[22] Glazer, J. and T. G.McGuire (2000), “Optimal risk adjustment in markets with adverse selection: An application to managed care.” American Economic Review, 90 (4), 1055-1071.
[23] Glazer, J. and T. G.McGuire (2011), “Gold and silver health plans: Accommodating demand heterogeneity in managed competition.” Journal of Health Economics, 30 (5), 1011-1019.
[24] Hackmann, M. B., J. T.Kolstad, and A. E.Kowalski (2015), “Adverse selection and an individual mandate: When theory meets practice.” American Economic Review, 105 (3), 1030-1066.
[25] Handel, B., I.Hendel, and M. D.Whinston (2015), “Equilibria in health exchanges: Adverse selection versus reclassification risk.” Econometrica, 83 (4), 1261-1313. 10.3982/ECTA12480 · Zbl 1419.91370
[26] Handel, B. R. (2013), “Adverse selection and inertia in health insurance markets: When nudging hurts.” American Economic Review, 103 (7), 2643-2682.
[27] Handel, B. R., J. T.Kolstad, and J.Spinnewijn (2015), “Information frictions and adverse selection: Policy interventions in health insurance markets.” Working Paper 21759, National Bureau of Economic Research.
[28] Kaiser Family Foundation and the Health Research and Educational Trust (2007), “Annual Survey of Employer Health Benefits, 2007.”
[29] Layton, T. (2014), “Imperfect risk adjustment, risk preferences, and sorting in competitive health insurance markets.” Working paper.
[30] Layton, T. J., R. P.Ellis, and T. G.McGuire (2015), “Assessing incentives for adverse selection in health plan payment systems.” Working Paper 21531, National Bureau of Economic Research.
[31] Levin, J. (2001), “Information and the market for lemons.” RAND Journal of Economics, 657-666.
[32] Mahoney, N. (2015), “Bankruptcy as implicit health insurance.” American Economic Review, 105 (2), 710-746.
[33] Manning, W. G., J. P.Newhouse, N.Duan, E. B.Keeler, and A.Leibowitz (1987), “Health insurance and the demand for medical care: Evidence from a randomized experiment.” American Economic Review, 251-277.
[34] Rothschild, M. and J.Stiglitz (1976), “Equilibrium in competitive insurance markets: An essay on the economics of imperfect information.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 90 (4), 629-649.
[35] Starc, A. (2014), “Insurer pricing and consumer welfare: Evidence from medigap.” RAND Journal of Economics, 45 (1), 198-220.
[36] Van de Ven, W. P. M. M. and R. P.Ellis (2000), “Risk adjustment in competitive health plan markets.” In Handbook of Health Economics, Vol. 1 (A. J.Culyer (ed.) and J. P.Newhouse (ed.), eds.), 755-845, Elsevier.
This reference list is based on information provided by the publisher or from digital mathematics libraries. Its items are heuristically matched to zbMATH identifiers and may contain data conversion errors. In some cases that data have been complemented/enhanced by data from zbMATH Open. This attempts to reflect the references listed in the original paper as accurately as possible without claiming completeness or a perfect matching.