×

Exploring the scope of neurometrically informed mechanism design. (English) Zbl 1393.91087

Summary: A basic goal in mechanism design is to construct mechanisms that simultaneously satisfy efficiency, voluntary participation, and dominant strategy incentive compatibility. Previous work has shown that this is impossible, unless the agents and planner have sufficient information about each other and common knowledge. These results have remained largely theoretical because the required information is generally not available in practical applications. However, recent work has shown that these limitations can be overcome in simple settings, using neurometric technologies that provide noisy signals of subjects’ preferences that can be used in the mechanism design problem. Here we build on this work by carrying out two new experiments designed to test the extent to which these Neurometrically Informed Mechanisms (NIMs) can be applied to more complicated and realistic environments. We find robustness to large type and action space and to the degrees of loss and risk-aversion observed in most of our sample.

MSC:

91B26 Auctions, bargaining, bidding and selling, and other market models
91A90 Experimental studies
91B18 Public goods

References:

[1] Aboyoun, D. C.; Dabbs, J. M., The Hess pupil dilation findings: sex or novelty?, Soc. Behavior Personal.: Int. J., 26, 415-419 (1998)
[2] Abreu, D.; Matsushima, H., A response to Glazer and Rosenthal, Econometrica, 60, 1439-1442 (1992)
[3] Attiyeh, G.; Franciosi, R.; Isaac, R. M., Experiments with the pivot process for providing public goods, Public Choice, 102, 95-114 (2000)
[4] Barelli, P., On the genericity of full surplus extraction in mechanism design, J. Econ. Theory, 144, 1320-1332 (2009) · Zbl 1159.91373
[5] Baron, D. P.; Besanko, D., Regulation, asymmetric information, and auditing, RAND J. Econ., 15, 447-470 (1984)
[6] Bartra, O.; McGuire, J. T.; Kable, J. W., The valuation system: a coordinate-based meta-analysis of BOLD fMRI experiments examining neural correlates of subjective value, NeuroImage, 76, 412-427 (2013)
[7] Border, K. C.; Sobel, J., Samurai accountant: a theory of auditing and plunder, Rev. Econ. Stud., 54, 525-540 (1987) · Zbl 0627.90005
[8] Bradley, M. M., Emotion and motivation, (Cacioppo, J. T.; Tassinary, L. G.; Berntson, G. G., Handbook of Psychophysiology (2000), Cambridge University Press)
[9] Bradley, M. M.; Miccoli, L.; Escrig, M. A.; Lang, P. J., The pupil as a measure of emotional arousal and autonomic activation, Psychophysiology, 45, 602-607 (2008)
[10] Brier, G. W., Probabilistic forecasts of precipitation in terms of quantiles using NWP model output, Monthly Weather Rev., 132, 338-347 (1950)
[11] Cason, T. N.; Saijo, T.; Sjöström, T.; Yamato, T., Secure implementation experiments: do strategy-proof mechanisms really work?, Games Econ. Behav., 57, 206-235 (2006) · Zbl 1154.91387
[12] Cason, T. N.; Plott, C. R., Misconceptions and game form recognition: challenges to theories of revealed preference and framing, J. Polit. Economy, 122, 1235-1270 (2014)
[13] Chen, Y.; Sönmez, T., School choice: an experimental study, J. Econ. Theory, 127, 202-231 (2006) · Zbl 1122.91054
[14] Chib, V. S.; Rangel, A.; Shimojo, S.; O’Doherty, J. P., Evidence for a common representation of decision values for dissimilar goods in human ventromedial prefrontal cortex, J. Neurosci., 29, 12315-12320 (2009)
[15] Chou, E.; McConnell, M.; Nagel, R.; Plott, C. R., The control of game form recognition in experiments: understanding dominant strategy failures in a simple two person ‘guessing’ game, Exper. Econ., 12, 159-179 (2009) · Zbl 1175.91048
[16] Clarke, E., Multi-part pricing of public goods, Public Choice, 11, 17-33 (1972)
[17] Clithero, J. A.; Carter, R. M.; Huettel, S. A., Local pattern classification differentiates processes of economic valuation, NeuroImage, 45, 1329-1338 (2009)
[18] Coppinger, V.; Smith, V. L.; Titus, J., Incentives and behavior in English, Dutch, and sealed-bid auctions, Econ. Inquiry, 18, 1-22 (1980)
[19] Cox, D. D.; Savoy, R. L., Functional magnetic resonance imaging (fMRI) “brain reading”: detecting and classifying distributed patterns of fMRI activity in human visual cortex, NeuroImage, 19, 261-270 (2003)
[20] Crémer, J.; McLean, R. P., Optimal selling strategies under uncertainty for a discriminating monopolist when demands are interdependent, Econometrica, 53, 345-361 (1985) · Zbl 0567.90011
[21] Cremer, J.; McLean, R. P., Full extraction of the surplus in Bayesian and dominant strategy auctions, Econometrica, 56, 1247-1257 (1988) · Zbl 0661.90104
[22] D’Aspremont, C.; Gerard-Varet, L., Incentives and incomplete information, J. Public Econ., 11, 25-45 (1979)
[23] De Martino, B.; Kumaran, D.; Seymour, B.; Dolan, R. J., Frames, biases, and rational decision-making in the human brain, Science, 313, 684-687 (2006)
[24] De Martino, B.; Camerer, C. F.; Adolphs, R., Amygdala damage eliminates monetary loss aversion, Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci., 107, 3788-3792 (2010)
[25] Dimberg, U.; Thunberg, M.; Elmehed, K., Unconscious facial reactions to emotional facial expressions, Psychol. Sci., 11, 86-89 (2000)
[26] Echenique, F.; Wilson, A. J.; Yariv, L., Clearinghouses for two-sided matching: an experimental study (2009), California Institute of Technology, Social Science Working Paper 1315
[27] Featherstone, C. R.; Niederle, M., Improving on strategy-proof school choice mechanisms: an experimental investigation (2014), Stanford working paper
[28] Fehr, E.; Rangel, A., Neuroeconomic foundations of economic choice - recent advances, J. Econ. Perspect., 25, 3-30 (2011)
[29] Georganas, S.; Levin, D.; McGee, P., A new perspective on overbidding in private-value auctions (2015), Working Paper
[30] Gibbard, A., Manipulation of voting schemes: a general result, Econometrica, 41, 587-601 (1973) · Zbl 0325.90081
[31] Gottfried, J. A.; O’Doherty, J.; Dolan, R. J., Encoding predictive reward value in human amygdala and orbitofrontal cortex, Science, 301, 1104-1107 (2003)
[32] Green, J.; Laffont, J. J., Characterization of satisfactory mechanisms for the revelation of preferences for public goods, Econometrica, 45, 427-438 (1977) · Zbl 0366.90021
[33] Gneithing, T.; Raftery, A. E., Strictly proper scoring rules, prediction, and estimation, J. Amer. Statistical Assoc., 102, 359-378 (2007) · Zbl 1284.62093
[34] Gross, J.; Woelbert, E.; Zimmermann, J.; Okamoto-Barth, S.; Riedl, A.; Goebel, R., Value signals in the prefrontal cortex predict individual preferences across reward categories, J. Neurosci., 34, 22, 7580-7586 (2014)
[35] Groves, T., Incentives in teams, Econometrica, 41, 617-631 (1973) · Zbl 0311.90002
[36] Groves, T.; Ledyard, J., Optimal allocation of public goods: a solution to the ‘free-rider’ problem, Econometrica, 45, 783-809 (1977) · Zbl 0363.90015
[37] Hare, T. A.; O’Doherty, J.; Camerer, C. F.; Schultz, W.; Rangel, A., Dissociating the role of the orbitofrontal cortex and the striatum in the computation of goal values and prediction errors, J. Neurosci., 28, 5623-5630 (2008)
[38] Hare, T. A.; Camerer, C. F.; Rangel, A., Self-control in decision-making involves modulation of the vmPFC valuation system, Science, 324, 646-648 (2009)
[39] Harstad, R. M., Dominant strategy adoption and bidders’ experience with pricing rules, Exper. Econ., 3, 261-280 (2000)
[40] Haxby, J. V.; Gobbini, M. I.; Furey, M. L.; Ishai, A.; Schouten, J. L.; Pietrini, P., Distributed and overlapping representations of faces and objects in ventral temporal cortex, Science, 293, 2425-2430 (2001)
[41] Haynes, J.; Sakai, K.; Rees, G.; Gilbert, S.; Frith, C.; Passingham, R., Reading hidden intention in the human brain, Current Biol., 17, 323-328 (2007)
[42] Healy, P. J., Learning dynamics for mechanism design: an experimental comparison of public goods mechanisms, J. Econ. Theory, 129, 114-149 (2006) · Zbl 1132.91431
[43] Heifetz, A.; Neeman, Z., On the generic (im)possibility of full surplus extraction in mechanism design, Econometrica, 74, 213-233 (2006) · Zbl 1112.91024
[44] Hsu, M.; Krajbich, I.; Zhao, C.; Camerer, C. F., Neural response to reward anticipation under risk is nonlinear in probabilities, J. Neurosci., 29, 2231-2237 (2009)
[45] Hurwicz, L., On informationally decentralized systems, (McGuire, B.; Radner, R., Decision and Organization (1972), North Holland: North Holland Amsterdam), 297-336 · Zbl 0254.90009
[46] Hurwicz, L.; Walker, M., On the generic nonoptimality of dominant-strategy allocation mechanisms: a general theorem that includes pure exchange economies, Econometrica, 58, 683-704 (1990) · Zbl 0728.90027
[47] Kable, J. W.; Glimcher, P. W., The neural correlates of subjective value during intertemporal choice, Nat. Neurosci., 10, 1625-1633 (2007)
[48] Kagel, J. H.; Harstad, R. M.; Levin, D., Information impact and allocation rules in auctions with affiliated private values: a laboratory study, Econometrica, 55, 1275-1304 (1987)
[49] Kahneman, D.; Tversky, A., Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk, Econometrica, 47, 263-291 (1979) · Zbl 0411.90012
[50] Kamitani, Y.; Tong, F., Decoding the visual and subjective contents of the human brain, Nat. Neurosci., 8, 679-685 (2005)
[51] Kawagoe, T.; Mori, T., Can the Pivotal mechanism induce truth-telling? An experimental study, Public Choice, 108, 331-354 (2001)
[52] Kay, K. N.; Naselaris, T.; Prenger, R. J.; Gallant, J. L., Identifying natural images from human brain activity, Nature, 452, 352-355 (2008)
[53] Knutson, B.; Adams, C. M.; Fong, G. W.; Hommer, D., Anticipation of increasing monetary reward selectively recruits nucleus accumbens, J. Neurosci., 21, Article RC159 pp. (2001)
[55] Krajbich, I.; Camerer, C. F.; Ledyard, J.; Rangel, A., Using neural measures of economic value to solve the public goods free-rider problem, Science, 326, 596-599 (2009)
[56] Laffont, J. J.; Martimort, D., Mechanism design with collusion and correlation, Econometrica, 68, 309-342 (2000)
[57] Lang, P. J.; Greenwald, M. K.; Bradley, M. M.; Hamm, A. O., Looking at pictures: affective, facial, visceral, and behavioral reactions, Psychophysiology, 30, 261-273 (1993)
[58] Lebreton, M.; Jorge, S.; Michel, V.; Thirion, B.; Pessiglione, M., An automatic valuation system in the human brain: evidence from functional neuroimaging, Neuron, 64, 431-439 (2009)
[59] Ledyard, J. O., Public Goods: A Survey of Experimental Research, Handbook of Experimental Economics (1995), Princeton University Press
[60] Levy, I.; Snell, J.; Nelson, A. J.; Rustichini, A.; Glimcher, P. W., Neural representation of subjective value under risk and ambiguity, J. Neurophysiol., 103, 1036-1047 (2010)
[61] Levy, I.; Lazzaro, S. C.; Rutledge, R. B.; Glimcher, P. W., Choice from non-choice: predicting consumer preferences from blood oxygenation level-dependent signals obtained during passive viewing, J. Neurosci., 31, 118-125 (2011)
[62] Lindahl, E., Just taxation-a positive solution, (Musgrave, Richard; Peacock, Alan, Classics in the Theory of Public Finance (1958), Macmillan: Macmillan London), 98-123
[63] Maskin, E. S., Nash equilibrium and welfare optimality, Rev. Econ. Stud., 66, 23-38 (1999) · Zbl 0956.91034
[64] McAfee, R. P.; Reny, P. J., Correlated information and mechanism design, Econometrica, 60, 395-421 (1992) · Zbl 0761.90024
[65] McClure, S. M.; Berns, G. S.; Montague, P. R., Temporal prediction errors in a passive learning task activate human striatum, Neuron, 38, 339-346 (2003)
[66] Murray, E. A., The amygdala, reward and emotion, Trends Cognitive Sci., 11, 489-497 (2007)
[67] Myerson, R., Optimal auction design, Math. Oper. Res., 6, 58-73 (1981) · Zbl 0496.90099
[68] Neeman, Z., The relevance of private information in mechanism design, J. Econ. Theory, 117, 55-77 (2004) · Zbl 1094.91038
[69] Norman, K. A.; Polyn, S. M.; Detre, G. J.; Haxby, J. V., Beyond mind-reading: multi-voxel pattern analysis of fMRI data, Trends Cognitive Sci., 10, 424-430 (2006)
[70] Noussair, C.; Robin, S.; Ruffieux, B., Revealing consumers’ willingness-to-pay: a comparison of the bdm mechanism and the Vickrey auction, J. Econ. Psych., 25, 725-741 (2004)
[71] O’Doherty, J.; Dayan, P.; Schultz, J.; Deichmann, R.; Friston, K.; Dolan, R. J., Dissociable roles of ventral and dorsal striatum in instrumental conditioning, Science, 304, 452-454 (2004)
[72] O’Toole, A. J.; Jiang, F.; Abdi, H.; Penard, N.; Dunlop, J. P.; Parent, M. A., Theoretical, statistical, and practical perspectives on pattern-based classification approaches to the analysis of functional neuroimaging data, J. Cognitive Neurosci., 19, 1735-1752 (2007)
[73] Pagnoni, G.; Zink, C. F.; Montague, P. R.; Berns, G. S., Activity in human ventral striatum locked to errors of reward prediction, Nat. Neurosci., 5, 97-98 (2002)
[74] Partala, T.; Jokiniemi, M.; Surakka, V., Pupillary responses to emotionally provocative stimuli, (The 2000 Symposium on Eye Tracking Research & Applications (2000), ACM Palm Beach Gardens: ACM Palm Beach Gardens Florida, United States), 123-129
[75] Pessoa, L.; Padmala, S., Decoding near-threshold perception of fear from distributed single-trial brain activation, Cerebral Cortex, 17, 691-701 (2007)
[76] Plassmann, H.; O’Doherty, J.; Rangel, A., Orbitofrontal cortex encodes willingness to pay in everyday economic transactions, J. Neurosci., 27, 9984-9988 (2007)
[77] Plassmann, H.; O’Doherty, J.; Shiv, B.; Rangel, A., Marketing actions can modulate neural representations of experienced pleasantness, Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci., 105, 1050-1054 (2008)
[78] Polyn, S. M.; Natu, V. S.; Cohen, J. D.; Norman, K. A., Category-specific cortical activity precedes retrieval during memory search, Science, 310, 1963-1966 (2005)
[79] Preuschoff, K.; Quartz, S. R.; Bossaerts, P., Human insula activation reflects risk prediction errors as well as risk, J. Neurosci., 28, 2745-2752 (2008)
[80] Rangel, A.; Clithero, J., The computation of stimulus values in simple choice, Neuroeconomics: Decision Making Brain, 2, 125-147 (2013)
[81] Riordan, M. H.; Sappington, D. E.M., Optimal contracts with public ex post information, J. Econ. Theory, 45, 189-199 (1988) · Zbl 0637.90015
[82] Robert, J., Continuity in auction design, J. Econ. Theory, 55, 169-179 (1991) · Zbl 0747.90030
[83] Rubinstein, A., Irrational diversification in multiple decision problems, Eur. Econ. Rev., 46, 1369-1378 (2002)
[84] Satterthwaite, M., Strategy-proofness and Arrow’s conditions: existence and correspondence theorems for voting procedures and social welfare functions, J. Econ. Theory, 10, 187-217 (1975) · Zbl 0315.90088
[85] Schultz, W.; Dayan, P.; Montague, P. R., A neural substrate of prediction and reward, Science, 275, 1593-1599 (1997)
[86] Serences, J. T.; Boynton, G. M., Feature-based attentional modulations in the absence of direct visual stimulation, Neuron, 55, 301-312 (2007)
[87] Singer, T.; Critchley, H. D.; Preuschoff, K., A common role of insula in feelings, empathy and uncertainty, Trends Cognitive Sci., 13, 334-340 (2009)
[88] Smith, A.; Bernheim, B. D.; Camerer, C.; Rangel, A., Neural activity reveals preferences without choices, Amer. Econ. J.: Microeconomics, 6, 1-36 (2014)
[89] Sokol-Hessner, P.; Hsu, M.; Curley, N. G.; Delgado, M. R.; Camerer, C. F.; Phelps, E. A., Thinking like a trader selectively reduces individuals’ loss aversion, Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA, 106, 5035-5040 (2009)
[90] Tassinary, L. G.; Cacioppo, J. T., Unobservable facial actions and emotions, Psychol. Sci., 3, 28-33 (1992)
[91] Telpaz, A.; Webb, R.; Levy, D. J., Using EEG to predict consumers’ future choices, J. Marketing Res., 52, 511-529 (2015)
[92] Tom, S. M.; Fox, C. R.; Trepel, C.; Poldrack, R. A., The neural basis of loss aversion in decision-making under risk, Science, 315, 515-518 (2007)
[93] Valentin, V. V.; Dickinson, A.; O’Doherty, J. P., Determining the neural substrates of goal-directed learning in the human brain, J. Neurosci., 27, 4019-4026 (2007)
[94] Vickrey, W., Counterspeculation, auctions, and competitive sealed tenders, J. Finance, 16, 8-37 (1961)
[95] Walker, M., On the nonexistence of a dominant-strategy mechanism for making optimal public decisions, Econometrica, 48, 1521-1540 (1980) · Zbl 0443.90009
[96] Wallis, J. D.; Miller, E. K., Neuronal activity in primate dorsolateral and orbital prefrontal cortex during performance of a reward preference task, Eur. J. Neurosci., 18, 2069-2081 (2003)
[97] Wang, S.; Camerer, C.; Filliba, M., Bayesian adaptive design for optimal elictation of risk preferences (2010), Caltech working paper
This reference list is based on information provided by the publisher or from digital mathematics libraries. Its items are heuristically matched to zbMATH identifiers and may contain data conversion errors. In some cases that data have been complemented/enhanced by data from zbMATH Open. This attempts to reflect the references listed in the original paper as accurately as possible without claiming completeness or a perfect matching.