×

The properties of Kullback-Leibler divergence for the unit root hypothesis. (English) Zbl 1179.62124

Summary: The fundamental contributions made by Paul Newbold have highlighted how crucial it is to detect when economic time series have unit roots. This paper explores the effects that model specification has on our ability to do that. Asymptotic power, a natural choice to quantify these effects, does not accurately predict finite-sample power. Instead, here the Kullback-Leibler divergence between the unit root null and any alternative is used and its numeric and analytic properties are detailed.
Numerically it behaves in a similar way to finite-sample power. However, because it is analytically available we are able to prove that it is a minimizable function of the degree of trending in any included deterministic component and of the correlation of the underlying innovations. It is explicitly confirmed, therefore, that approximately linear trends and negative unit root moving average innovations minimize the efficacy of unit root inferential tools. Applied to the C. R. Nelson and C. I. Plosser [J. Monet. Econ. 10, 139–162 (1982)] macroeconomic series the effect that different types of trends included in the model have on unit root inference is clearly revealed.

MSC:

62M10 Time series, auto-correlation, regression, etc. in statistics (GARCH)
62F03 Parametric hypothesis testing
62P20 Applications of statistics to economics
Full Text: DOI

References:

[1] DOI: 10.2307/2999618 · Zbl 1056.62531 · doi:10.2307/2999618
[2] Phillips, Econometric Theory 23 pp 557– (2007)
[3] DOI: 10.1016/0304-4076(86)90001-1 · Zbl 0602.62098 · doi:10.1016/0304-4076(86)90001-1
[4] DOI: 10.1111/1468-0262.00256 · Zbl 1056.62529 · doi:10.1111/1468-0262.00256
[5] DOI: 10.2307/1913712 · Zbl 0683.62066 · doi:10.2307/1913712
[6] DOI: 10.1017/S026646660809018X · Zbl 1253.62060 · doi:10.1017/S026646660809018X
[7] DOI: 10.1016/0304-3932(82)90012-5 · doi:10.1016/0304-3932(82)90012-5
[8] Harris, Econometric Theory 25 pp 1548– (2009)
[9] DOI: 10.1017/S0266466607070296 · Zbl 1237.62121 · doi:10.1017/S0266466607070296
[10] DOI: 10.1016/0304-4076(74)90034-7 · Zbl 0319.62072 · doi:10.1016/0304-4076(74)90034-7
[11] Magnus, Matrix Differential Calculus, with Applications in Statistics and Econometrics (1999) · Zbl 0912.15003
[12] DOI: 10.2307/1403865 · Zbl 1217.62014 · doi:10.2307/1403865
[13] DOI: 10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00014-1 · Zbl 0944.62083 · doi:10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00014-1
[14] DOI: 10.2307/2171846 · Zbl 0888.62088 · doi:10.2307/2171846
[15] Kullback, Information Theory and Statistics (1997)
[16] DOI: 10.2307/1913101 · Zbl 0653.62068 · doi:10.2307/1913101
[17] DOI: 10.1016/0304-4076(91)90080-W · Zbl 0729.62079 · doi:10.1016/0304-4076(91)90080-W
[18] DOI: 10.1002/jae.3950060409 · doi:10.1002/jae.3950060409
[19] DOI: 10.1214/aos/1176325644 · Zbl 0821.62004 · doi:10.1214/aos/1176325644
[20] DOI: 10.2307/1391541 · doi:10.2307/1391541
[21] DOI: 10.1111/1467-6419.00064 · doi:10.1111/1467-6419.00064
[22] DOI: 10.1111/1468-0262.00419 · Zbl 1142.91719 · doi:10.1111/1468-0262.00419
[23] DOI: 10.1002/jae.3950060402 · doi:10.1002/jae.3950060402
This reference list is based on information provided by the publisher or from digital mathematics libraries. Its items are heuristically matched to zbMATH identifiers and may contain data conversion errors. In some cases that data have been complemented/enhanced by data from zbMATH Open. This attempts to reflect the references listed in the original paper as accurately as possible without claiming completeness or a perfect matching.