×

Decisions with endogenous frames. (English) Zbl 1239.91032

Summary: We develop a model of decision-making with endogenous frames and contrast the normative implications of our model to those of choice theoretic models in which observed choices are determined by exogenous frames or ancillary conditions. We argue that, frames, though they may be taken as given by the decision-maker at the point when choices are made, matter for both welfare and policy purposes.

MSC:

91B06 Decision theory

References:

[1] Appadurai (2004) The capacity to aspire: culture and the terms of recognition. In: Rao V, Walton M (eds) Culture and public action. IBRD-World Bank, Washington
[2] Ariely D, Wertenbroch K (2002) Procrastination, deadlines, and performance: self-control by precommitment. Psychol Sci 13(3): 219–224 · doi:10.1111/1467-9280.00441
[3] Bandura A (1986) Social foundations of thought and action: a social cognitive theory. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs
[4] Baron J (2008) Thinking and deciding. 4. Cambridge University Press, NY
[5] Bernheim BD (2009) Behavioral welfare economics. J Eur Econ Assoc 7(2–3): 267–319 · doi:10.1162/JEEA.2009.7.2-3.267
[6] Bernheim BD, Rangel A (2007) Toward choice-theoretic foundations for behavioral welfare economics. Am Econ Rev 97(2): 464–470 · doi:10.1257/aer.97.2.464
[7] Bernheim BD, Rangel A (2008) Beyond revealed preference: choice-theoretic foundations for behavioral welfare economics. NBER, WP 13737 · Zbl 1182.91070
[8] Bernheim BD, Rangel A (2009) Beyond revealed preference: choice-theoretic foundations for behavioral welfare economics. Q J Econ 124(1): 51–104 · Zbl 1182.91070 · doi:10.1162/qjec.2009.124.1.51
[9] Carrillo J, Mariotti T (2000) Strategic ignorance as a self-disciplining device. Rev Econ Stud 67: 529–544 · Zbl 1055.91508 · doi:10.1111/1467-937X.00142
[10] Dalton P, Ghosal S (2010) Behavioral decisions and welfare. CentER Discussion Paper, 2010–2022
[11] Easterlin RA (2001) Income and happiness: towards a unified theory. Econ J 111: 465–484 · doi:10.1111/1468-0297.00646
[12] Elster J (1998) Emotions and economic theory. J Econ Lit 36(1): 47–74
[13] Ghosal S (2011) Complementarity with complete but P-acyclic preferences. Math Soc Sci 62(2): 120–122 · Zbl 1279.91057 · doi:10.1016/j.mathsocsci.2011.06.003
[14] Harsanyi JS (1954) Welfare economics of variable tastes. Rev Econ Stud 3(21): 204–213
[15] Kahneman D, Sugden R (2005) Experienced utility as a standard of policy evaluation. Environ Resour Econ 32: 161–181 · doi:10.1007/s10640-005-6032-4
[16] Kahneman D, Tversky A (1979) Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47(2): 263–291 · Zbl 0411.90012 · doi:10.2307/1914185
[17] Munro A, Sugden R (2003) On the theory of reference-dependent preferences. J Econ Behav Organ 50: 407–428 · doi:10.1016/S0167-2681(02)00033-1
[18] Rubinstein A, Salant Y (2008) (A, f) Choice with Frames. Rev Econ Stud 75: 1287–1296 · Zbl 1144.91312 · doi:10.1111/j.1467-937X.2008.00510.x
[19] Sen A (1977) Rational fools: a critique of the behavioral foundations of economic theory. Philos Pub Affairs 6(4): 317–344
[20] Stern N, Dethier J-J, Rogers FH (2005) Growth and empowerment Making development happen, Munich lectures in economics. The MIT Press, Cambridge
[21] Thaler R, Sunstein CR (2003) Libertarian Paternalism. Am Econ Rev 93(2): 175–179 · doi:10.1257/000282803321947001
[22] Tversky A, Kahneman D (1991) Loss aversion in riskless choice: a reference-dependent model. Q J Econ 106(4): 1039–1061 · doi:10.2307/2937956
[23] World Bank (2002) Empowerment and poverty reduction: a sourcebook. preliminary draft, pp 280
This reference list is based on information provided by the publisher or from digital mathematics libraries. Its items are heuristically matched to zbMATH identifiers and may contain data conversion errors. In some cases that data have been complemented/enhanced by data from zbMATH Open. This attempts to reflect the references listed in the original paper as accurately as possible without claiming completeness or a perfect matching.