×

Climate change and market collapse: a model applied to Darfur. (English) Zbl 1405.91495

Summary: A recurring argument in the global debate is that climate deterioration is likely to make social conflicts over diminishing natural resources more common in the future. The exact mechanism behind such a development has so far not been successfully characterized in the literature. In this paper, we present a general model of a community populated by farmers and herders who can either divide up land in a market economy or in autarky. The key insight from our model is that decreasing resources can make trade between the two groups collapse, which in turn makes each group’s welfare independent of that of the other. Predictions from the model are then applied to the conflict in Darfur. Our analysis suggests that three decades of drought in the area can at least partially explain the observed disintegration of markets and the subsequent rise of social tensions.

MSC:

91B76 Environmental economics (natural resource models, harvesting, pollution, etc.)
91B26 Auctions, bargaining, bidding and selling, and other market models

References:

[1] Burke, M.B.; Miguel, E.; Satyanath, S.; Dykema, J.A.; Lobell, D.B.; Warming Increases the Risk of Civil War in Africa; PNAS: 2009; Volume 106 ,20670-20674.
[2] Miguel, E.; Satyanath, S.; Sergenti, E.; Economic Shocks and Civil Conflict: An Instrumental Variables Approach; J. Political Econ.: 2004; Volume 112 ,725-753.
[3] Blattman, C.; Miguel, E.; Civil War; J. Econ. Lit.: 2010; Volume 48 ,3-57.
[4] Hsiang, S.; Burke, M.; Miguel, E.; Quantifying the Influence of Climate on Human Conflict; Science: 2013; Volume 341 ,13.
[5] Buhaug, H.; Nordkvelle, J.; Bernauer, T.; Böhmelt, T.; Brzoska, M.; Busby, J.W.; Ciccone, A.; Fjelde, H.; Gartzke, E.; One effect to rule them all? A comment on climate and conflict; Clim. Chang.: 2014; Volume 127 ,391-397.
[6] Zhang, D.D.; Brecke, P.; Lee, H.F.; He, Y.-Q.; Zhang, J.; Global climate change, war, and population decline in recent human history; PNAS: 2007; Volume 104 ,19214-19219.
[7] Kennett, D.J.; Breitenbach, S.F.M.; Aquino, V.V.; Asmerom, Y.; Awe, J.; Baldini, J.U.L.; Bartlein, P.; Culleton, B.J.; Ebert, C.; Jazwa, C.; Development and Disintegration of Maya Political Systems in Response to Climate Change; Science: 2012; Volume 338 ,788-791.
[8] Schubert, R.; Schellnhuber, H.J.; Buchmann, N.; Epiney, A.; Grieβhammer, R.; Kulessa, M.; Messner, D.; Rahmstorf, S.; Schmid, J.; Climate Change as a Security Risk, German Advisory Council on Global Change; 2008; .
[9] Homer-Dixon, T.; On the Threshold: Environmental Changes as Causes of Acute Conflict; Int. Secur.: 1991; Volume 16 ,76-116.
[10] Homer-Dixon, T.; Environmental Scarcities and Violent Conflict: Evidence from Cases; Int. Secur.: 1994; Volume 19 ,5-40.
[11] Diamond, J.; ; Collapse: How Societies Choose to Fail or Succeed: New York, NY, USA 2005; .
[12] Skaperdas, S.; Contest Success Functions; Econ. Theory: 1996; Volume 7 ,283-290. · Zbl 0852.90137
[13] Olsson, O.; Congdon Fors, H.; Congo: The Prize of Predation; J. Peace Res.: 2004; Volume 41 ,321-336.
[14] Brander, J.A.; Taylor, S.; The Simple Economics of Easter Island: A Ricardo-Malthus Model or Renewable Resource Use; Am. Econ. Rev.: 1998; Volume 88 ,119-138.
[15] Reuveny, R.; Maxwell, J.W.; Conflict and Renewable Resources; J. Confl. Resolut.: 2001; Volume 45 ,719-742.
[16] Sherif, M.; Harvey, O.J.; White, B.J.; Hood, W.R.; Sherif, C.W.; ; The Robbers Cave Experiment: Intergroup Conflict and Cooperation: Middletown, CT, USA 1961; .
[17] Tajfel, H.; Flament, C.; Billig, M.; Bundy, R.; Social categorization and inter-group behavior; Eur. J. Soc. Psychol.: 1971; Volume 1 ,149-178.
[18] Rodrik, D.; Where did all the growth go? External shocks, social conflict, and growth collapses; J. Econ. Growth: 1999; Volume 4 ,385-412. · Zbl 0962.91057
[19] Dalgaard, C.-J.; Olsson, O.; Why Are Rich Countries More Politically Cohesive?; Scand. J. Econ.: 2013; Volume 115 ,423-448.
[20] Rohner, D.; Thoenig, M.; Zilibotti, F.; War Signals: A Theory of Trade, Trust, and Conflict; Rev. Econ. Stud.: 2013; Volume 80 ,1114-1147. · Zbl 1272.91104
[21] Copeland, B; Taylor, S; Trade, tragedy and the commons; Am. Econ. Rev.: 2009; Volume 99 ,725-749.
[22] Engel, S.; Lopez, R.; Palmer, C.; Community-Industry Contracting over Natural Resource Use in a Context of Weak Property Rights; Environ. Resour. Econ.: 2006; Volume 33 ,73-93.
[23] van den Brink, R.; Bromley, D.; Chavas, J.P.; The Economics of Cain and Abel: Agro-Pastoral property Rights in the Sahel; J. Dev. Stud.: 1995; Volume 31 ,373-399.
[24] Turner, D.; Political Ecology and the Moral Dimensions of Resource Conflicts: The Case of Farmer-Herder Conflicts in the Sahel; Political Geogr.: 2004; Volume 23 ,863-889.
[25] Olsson, O.; Siba, E.; Ethnic cleansing or resource struggle in Darfur? An empirical analysis; J. Dev. Econ.: 2013; Volume 103 ,299-312.
[26] Olsson, O.; After Janjaweed? Socioeconomic Impacts of the Conflict in Darfur; World Bank Econ. Rev.: 2010; Volume 24 ,386-411.
[27] Alix-Garcia, J.; Bartlett, A.; Saah, D.; The Landscape of Conflict: IDPs, Aid, and Land-Use Change in Darfur; J. Econ. Geogr.: 2013; Volume 13 ,589-617.
[28] De Juan, A.; Long-term Environmental Change and Geographical Patterns of Violence in Darfur, 2003-2005; Political Geogr.: 2015; Volume 45 ,22-33.
[29] De Waal, A.; Hazlett, C.; Davenport, C.; Kennedy, J.; The Epidemiology of Lethal Violence in Darfur: Using Micro-Data to Explore Complex Patterns of Ongoing Armed Conflict; Soc. Sci. Med.: 2014; Volume 120 ,368-377.
[30] Vanrooyen, M.; Leaning, J.; Johnson, K.; Hirschfeld, K.; Tuller, D.; Levine, A.; Hefferman, J.; Employment of a Livelihoods Analysis to Define Genocide in the Darfur Region of Sudan; J. Genocide Res.: 2008; Volume 10 ,343-358.
[31] Binmore, K.; Rubinstein, A.; Wolinsky, A.; The Nash Bargaining Solution in Economic Modelling; Rand J. Econ.: 1986; Volume 17 ,176-188.
[32] Flint, J.; De Waal, A.; ; Darfur: A New History of a Long War (Revised and Updated): New York, NY, USA 2008; .
[33] Collier, P.; Hoeffler, A.; Greed and Grievance in Civil War; Oxf. Econ. Pap.: 2004; Volume 56 ,563-595.
[34] Mehlum, H.; Moene, K.; Torvik, R.; Institutions and the Resource Curse; Econ. J.: 2006; Volume 116 ,1-20.
[35] Olsson, O.; Conflict Diamonds; J. Dev. Econ.: 2007; Volume 82 ,267-286.
[36] van der Ploeg, F.; Natural Resources: Curse of Blessing?; J. Econ. Lit.: 2011; Volume 49 ,366-420.
[37] Stern, N.; ; Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change: Cambridge, UK 2006; .
[38] ; IPCC Fourth Assessment Report, Working Group II: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerablility: Cambridge, UK 2007; .
[39] ; Sudan: Post-Conflict Environmental Assessment: Nairobi, Kenya 2007; .
[40] Degomme, O.; Guha-Sapir, D.; Patterns of Mortality Rates in Darfur Conflict; Lancet: 2010; Volume 375 ,294-300.
[41] Darfur Joint Assessment Mission: Status of Natural Resources and the Environment, Republic of Sudan; 2006; .
[42] ; United Nations. Report of the International Commission of Inquiry on Darfur to the United Nations Secretary General: Geneva, Switzerland 2005; .
[43] Prunier, G.; ; Darfur: The Ambiguous Genocide: New York, NY, USA 2007; .
[44] Kevane, M.; Gray, L.; Darfur: Rainfall and Conflict; Environ. Res. Lett.: 2008; Volume 3 ,1-10.
[45] Return-Oriented Profiling in the Southern Part of West Darfur and Corresponding Chadian Border Area UNHCR/INTERSOS; 2005; .
This reference list is based on information provided by the publisher or from digital mathematics libraries. Its items are heuristically matched to zbMATH identifiers and may contain data conversion errors. In some cases that data have been complemented/enhanced by data from zbMATH Open. This attempts to reflect the references listed in the original paper as accurately as possible without claiming completeness or a perfect matching.