×

The network origins of the gains from trade. (English) Zbl 1533.91310

Summary: This paper develops a network perspective on the gains from trade in today’s international supply chains. In particular, we demonstrate that the comparative statics predictions of a standard general-equilibrium trade model with input-output linkages can be expressed as a network diffusion model. This model captures the relevant dimensions of the production network’s structure by just two easily quantifiable statistics: A country’s upstream exposure to supply shocks further up in the network and its downstream exposure to demand shocks further down. We then show how up- and downstream exposure crucially determine the welfare effects from various types of trade cost shocks. In some cases, they even capture the entire welfare effect.

MSC:

91B60 Trade models
91B50 General equilibrium theory

References:

[1] Acemoglu, D.; Carvalho, V. M.; Ozdaglar, A.; Tahbaz-Salehi, A., The network origins of aggregate fluctuations, Econometrica, 80, 5, 1977-2016, (2012) · Zbl 1274.91317
[2] Adao, R.; Costinot, A.; Donaldson, D., Nonparametric counterfactual predictions in neoclassical models of international trade, Am. Econ. Rev., 107, 3, 633-689, (2017)
[3] Alvarez, F.; Lucas, R. E., General equilibrium analysis of the Eaton-Kortum model of international trade, J. Monet. Econ., 54, 1726-1768, (2007)
[4] Antràs, P.; Chor, D., Organizing the global value chain, Econometrica, 81, 6, 2127-2204, (2013) · Zbl 1288.91130
[5] Antràs, P.; Chor, D.; Fally, T.; Hillberry, R., Measuring the upstreamness of production and trade flows, Am. Econ. Rev., 102, 3, 412-416, (2012)
[6] Antràs, P.; De Gortari, A., On the geography of global value chains, Econometrica, 88, 4, 1553-1598, (2020) · Zbl 1466.91174
[7] Antràs, P.; Staiger, R. W., Offshoring and the role of trade agreements, Am. Econ. Rev., 102, 7, 3140-3183, (2012)
[8] Arkolakis, C.; Costinot, A.; Rodríguez-Clare, A., New trade models, same old gains?, Am. Econ. Rev., 102, 1, 94-130, (2012)
[9] Armington, P. S., A theory of demand for products distinguished by place of production, IMF Staff Pap., 16, 159-178, (1969)
[10] Atalay, E., How important are sectoral shocks?, Am. Econ. J. Macroecon., 9, 4, 254-280, (2017)
[11] Ballester, C.; Calvó-Armengol, A.; Zenou, Y., Who’s who in networks. Wanted: the key player, Econometrica, 74, 5, 1403-1417, (2006) · Zbl 1138.91590
[12] Banerjee, A.; Chandrasekhar, A. G.; Duflo, E.; Jackson, M. O., The diffusion of microfinance, Science, 341, 6144, (2013)
[13] Baqaee, D. R.; Farhi, E., The macroeconomic impact of microeconomic shocks: beyond hulten’s theorem, Econometrica, 87, 4, 1155-1203, (2019) · Zbl 1426.91160
[14] Baqaee, D.R., Farhi, E., 2022. Networks, barriers, and trade. Unpublished manuscript.
[15] Barrot, J.-N.; Sauvagnat, J., Input specificity and the propagation of idiosyncratic shocks in production networks, Q. J. Econ., 131, 3, 1543-1592, (2016)
[16] Bems, R.; Johnson, R. C.; Yi, K.-M., Vertical linkages and the collapse of global trade, Am. Econ. Rev., 101, 3, 308-312, (2011)
[17] Blaum, J.; Lelarge, C.; Peters, M., The gains from input trade with heterogeneous importers, Am. Econ. J. Macroecon., 10, 4, 77-127, (2018)
[18] Boehm, C. E.; Flaaen, A.; Pandalai-Nayar, N., Input linkages and the transmission of shocks: firm-level evidence from the 2011 Tōhoku earthquake, Rev. Econ. Stat., 101, 1, 60-75, (2019)
[19] Bonacich, P., Power and centrality: a family of measures, Am. J. Sociol., 92, 1170-1182, (1987)
[20] Caliendo, L.; Parro, F., Estimates of the trade and welfare effects of NAFTA, Rev. Econ. Stud., 82, 1, 1-44, (2015) · Zbl 1405.91378
[21] Caselli, F.; Koren, M.; Lisicky, M.; Tenreyro, S., Diversification through trade, Q. J. Econ., 135, 1, 449-502, (2020) · Zbl 1431.91229
[22] Costinot, A.; Vogel, J.; Wang, S., An elementary theory of global supply chains, Rev. Econ. Stud., 80, 109-144, (2013) · Zbl 1408.90007
[23] di Giovanni, J.; Levchenko, A. A.; Zhang, J., The global welfare impact of China: trade integration and technological change, Am. Econ. J. Macroecon., 6, 3, 153-183, (2014)
[24] Dixit, A. K.; Grossman, G. M., Trade and protection with multistage production, Rev. Econ. Stud., 49, 4, 583-594, (1982)
[25] Eaton, J.; Kortum, S., Technology, geography, and trade, Econometrica, 70, 5, 1741-1779, (2002) · Zbl 1137.91561
[26] Erbahar, A.; Zi, Y., Cascading trade protection: evidence from the us, J. Int. Econ., 108, 274-299, (2017)
[27] Ethier, W. J., Internationally decreasing costs and world trade, J. Int. Econ., 9, 1-24, (1979)
[28] Fally, T., 2012. Production staging: measurement and facts. Unpublished manuscript.
[29] Fally, T.; Hillberry, R., A coasian model of international production chains, J. Int. Econ., 114, 299-315, (2018)
[30] Foti, N. J.; Pauls, S.; Rockmore, D. N., Stability of the world trade web over time-an extinction analysis, J. Econ. Dyn. Control, 37, 9, 1889-1910, (2013) · Zbl 1402.91331
[31] Goyal, S.; Vigier, A., Attack, defence, and contagion in networks, Rev. Econ. Stud., 81, 4, 1518-1542, (2014) · Zbl 1405.91074
[32] Grassi, B., 2017. IO in IO: Competition and volatility in input-output networks. Unpublished manuscript.
[33] Grossman, G. M.; Rossi-Hansberg, E., Trading tasks: a simple theory of offshoring, Am. Econ. Rev., 98, 5, 1978-1997, (2008)
[34] Hulten, C. R., Growth accounting with intermediate inputs, Rev. Econ. Stud., 45, 3, 511-518, (1978) · Zbl 0426.90003
[35] Hummels, D.; Ishii, J.; Yi, K.-M., The nature and growth of vertical specialization in world trade, J. Int. Econ., 54, 75-96, (2001)
[36] Huneeus, F., 2018. Production network dynamics and the propagation of shocks. Unpublished manuscript.
[37] Huo, Z.; Levchenko, A. A.; Pandalai-Nayar, N., International comovement in the global production network, (2019), National Bureau of Economic Research, Technical report
[38] Jackson, M. O., A typology of social capital and associated network measures, Soc. Choice Welf., 54, 2, 311-336, (2020) · Zbl 1437.91186
[39] König, M. D.; Liu, X.; Zenou, Y., R&D networks: theory, empirics, and policy implications, Rev. Econ. Stat., 101, 3, 476-491, (2019)
[40] König, M. D.; Rohner, D.; Thoenig, M.; Zilibotti, F., Networks in conflict: theory and evidence from the great war of Africa, Econometrica, 85, 4, 1093-1132, (2017) · Zbl 1420.91403
[41] Krugman, P.; Venables, A. J., Globalization and the inequality of nations, Q. J. Econ., 110, 4, 857-880, (1995)
[42] Liu, E., Industrial policies in production networks, Q. J. Econ., 134, 4, 1883-1948, (2019) · Zbl 1425.91243
[43] Long, J. B.; Plosser, C. I., Real business cycles, J. Polit. Econ., 91, 1, 39-69, (1983)
[44] Lucas, R. E., Understanding business cycles, (Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 5, (1977), Elsevier), 7-29
[45] Mas-Collel, A.; Whinston, M.; Green, J., Microeconomic Theory, (1995), Oxford University Press: Oxford University Press New York · Zbl 1256.91002
[46] Morishima, M., On the three hicksian laws of comparative statics, Rev. Econ. Stud., 27, 3, 195-201, (1960)
[47] Ornelas, E.; Turner, J. L., Protection and international sourcing, Econ. J., 122, 559, 26-63, (2012)
[48] Ossa, R., Why trade matters after all, J. Int. Econ., 97, 2, 266-277, (2015)
[49] Redding, S.; Venables, A. J., Economic geography and international inequality, J. Int. Econ., 62, 53-82, (2004)
[50] Romalis, J., NAFTA’s and CUSFTA’s impact on international trade, Rev. Econ. Stat., 89, 3, 416-435, (2007)
[51] Samuelson, P. A., A fundamental multiplier identity, Econometrica, 221-226, (1943) · Zbl 0063.06684
[52] Timmer, M. P.; Erumban, A. A.; Los, B.; Stehrer, R.; de Vries, G. J., Slicing up global value chains, J. Econ. Perspect., 28, 2, 99-118, (2014)
[53] Tintelnot, F.; Kikkawa, A. K.; Mogstad, M.; Dhyne, E., Trade and domestic production networks, (2018), National Bureau of Economic Research, Technical report
[54] Yi, K.-M., Can vertical specialization explain the growth of world trade?, J. Polit. Econ., 111, 1, 52-102, (2003)
This reference list is based on information provided by the publisher or from digital mathematics libraries. Its items are heuristically matched to zbMATH identifiers and may contain data conversion errors. In some cases that data have been complemented/enhanced by data from zbMATH Open. This attempts to reflect the references listed in the original paper as accurately as possible without claiming completeness or a perfect matching.