×

The exact bias of the Banzhaf measure of power when votes are neither equiprobable nor independent. (English) Zbl 1163.91343

Summary: This paper discusses a numerical scheme for computing the Banzhaf swing probability when votes are neither equiprobable nor independent. Examples indicate a substantial bias in the Banzhaf measure of voting power if neither assumption is met. The analytical part derives the exact magnitude of the bias due to the common probability of an affirmative vote deviating from one half and due to common correlation in unweighted simple-majority games. The former bias is polynomial, the latter is linear. A modified square-root rule for two-tier voting systems that takes into account both the homogeneity and the size of constituencies is also provided.

MSC:

91B12 Voting theory
91A40 Other game-theoretic models
Full Text: DOI

References:

[1] Banzhaf JF (1965). Weighted voting does not work: a mathematical analysis. Rutgers Law Rev 19: 317–343
[2] Barbera S and Jackson MO (2006). On the weights of nations: assigning voting weights in a heterogeneous union. J Polit Econ 114: 317–339 · doi:10.1086/501172
[3] Berg S (1985). Paradox of voting under an urn-model: the effect of homogeneity. Pub Choice 47: 377–387 · doi:10.1007/BF00127533
[4] Berg S (1993). Condorcet’s jury theorem, dependency among jurors. Social Choice and Welfare 10: 87–95 · Zbl 0825.90042 · doi:10.1007/BF00187435
[5] Boland PJ (1989). Majority systems and the Condorcet jury theorem. Statistician 38: 181–189 · doi:10.2307/2348873
[6] Braham M and Holler M (2005). The impossibility of a preference-based power index. J Theor Polit 17: 137–157 · doi:10.1177/0951629805047801
[7] Braham M and Holler M (2005). Power and preferences again. A reply to Napel and Widgrén. J Theor Polit 17: 389–395 · doi:10.1177/0951629805052887
[8] Chamberlain G and Rothschild M (1981). A note on the probability of casting a decisive vote. J Econ Theory 25: 152–162 · Zbl 0474.90011 · doi:10.1016/0022-0531(81)90022-3
[9] Everitt BS (1992). The analysis of contingency tables. Chapman & Hall, London · Zbl 0803.62047
[10] Felsenthal DS, Machover M (1998) The measurement of voting power: theory and practice, problems and paradoxes. Edward Elgar · Zbl 0954.91019
[11] Garrett G and Tsebelis G (2001). Even more reasons to resist the temptation of power indices in the European Union. J Theor Polit 13: 99–105 · doi:10.1177/0951692801013001005
[12] Gelman A, Katz JN and Bafumi J (2004). Standard voting power indices don’t work: an empirical analysis. Br J Polit Sci 34: 657–674 · doi:10.1017/S0007123404000237
[13] Gelman A, Katz JN and Tuerlinckx F (2002). The mathematics and statistics of voting power. Stat Sci 17: 420–435 · Zbl 1062.91019 · doi:10.1214/ss/1049993201
[14] Good I and Mayer L (1975). Estimating the efficacy of a vote. Behav Sci 20: 25–33 · doi:10.1002/bs.3830200104
[15] Grofman B (1981). Fair apportionment and the Banzhaf index. Am Math Mont 88: 1–5 · Zbl 0451.90009 · doi:10.2307/2320703
[16] Hall AR (2005). Generalized method of moments. Advanced texts in econometrics. Oxford University Press, Oxford
[17] Kaniovski YM and Pflug GC (2007). Risk assessment for credit portfolios: a coupled Markov chain model. J Bank Finance 31: 2303–2323 · doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2007.02.005
[18] Kirman A, Widgrén M (1995) European economic decision-making policy: progress or paralysis? Econ Policy 10:423–460
[19] Leech D and Leech R (2006). Voting power and voting blocs. Pub Choice 127: 285–303 · doi:10.1007/s11127-006-1914-8
[20] Maaser N and Napel S (2007). Equal representation in two-tier voting systems. Soc Choice Welf 28: 401–420 · Zbl 1211.91101 · doi:10.1007/s00355-006-0186-z
[21] Merrill\(\sim\)III S and Grofman B (1999). A unified theory of voting: directional and proximity spatial models. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge · Zbl 0888.90036
[22] Napel S and Widgrén M (2004). Power measurement as sensitivity analysis: a unified approach. J Theor Polit 16: 517–538 · doi:10.1177/0951629804046152
[23] Napel S and Widgrén M (2005). The possibility of a preference-based power index. J Theor Polit 17: 377–387 · doi:10.1177/0951629805052886
[24] Owen G (1972). Multilinear extensions of games. Manage Sci 18: 64–79 · Zbl 0239.90049 · doi:10.1287/mnsc.18.5.64
[25] Page SE (2006). Path dependence. Q J Polit Sci 1: 87–115 · doi:10.1561/100.00000006
[26] Penrose LS (1946). The elementary statistics of majority voting. J R Stat Soc 109: 53–57 · doi:10.2307/2981392
[27] Shapley LS and Shubik M (1954). A method of evaluating the distribution of power in a committee system. Am Polit Sci Rev 48: 787–792 · doi:10.2307/1951053
[28] Steunenberg B, Schmidtchen D and Koboldt C (1999). Strategic power in the European Union: evaluating the distribution of power in policy games. J Theor Polit 11: 339–366 · doi:10.1177/0951692899011003005
[29] Straffin PD (1977). Homogeneity, independence and power indices. Pub Choice 30: 107–118 · doi:10.1007/BF01718820
[30] Straffin PD (1994). Power and stability in politics. In: Aumann, RJ and Hart, S (eds) Handbook of game theory, Vol 2, chap 32, pp. Elsevier, Amsterdam
[31] Tsebelis G (1995). Decision making in political systems: veto players in presidentialism, parliamentarism, multicameralism and multipartyism. Br J Polit Sci 25: 289–325 · doi:10.1017/S0007123400007225
[32] Widgrén M (1995). Probabilistic voting power in the EU Council: the cases of trade policy and social regulation. Scand J Econ 97: 345–356 · Zbl 0915.90077 · doi:10.2307/3440533
This reference list is based on information provided by the publisher or from digital mathematics libraries. Its items are heuristically matched to zbMATH identifiers and may contain data conversion errors. In some cases that data have been complemented/enhanced by data from zbMATH Open. This attempts to reflect the references listed in the original paper as accurately as possible without claiming completeness or a perfect matching.