×

When are groups less moral than individuals? (English) Zbl 1497.91102

Summary: Individuals are less likely to make morally desirable decisions when they are in groups. I study when this phenomenon makes groups less likely to produce a morally desirable outcome than one individual alone. I formulate and test a model in which a moral outcome occurs if at least one individual makes a costly decision. Using a lab experiment and data from field experiments on the bystander effect, I show that if most individuals are moral, the moral outcome is more likely to be produced by one individual, whereas if most individuals are immoral, it is more likely to be produced by a group. This rule is not only useful for reconciling previous mixed evidence on moral decision-making in groups, but may also be applied to better design organizations and institutions.

MSC:

91B10 Group preferences
91B08 Individual preferences

References:

[1] Andreoni, J., Impure altruism and donations to public goods: a theory of warm-glow giving, Econ. J., 100, 401, 464 (1990)
[2] Babcock, L.; Recalde, M. P.; Vesterlund, L.; Weingart, L., Gender differences in accepting and receiving requests for tasks with low promotability, Am. Econ. Rev., 107, 3, 714-747 (2017)
[3] Baland, J.-M.; Platteau, J.-P., Halting degradation of natural resources: is there a role for rural communities? (1996), Food & Agriculture Org.
[4] Barron, G.; Yechiam, E., Private e-mail requests and the diffusion of responsibility, Comput. Hum. Behav., 18, 5, 507-520 (2002)
[5] Bartling, B.; Özdemir, Y., The limits to moral erosion in markets: Social norms and the replacement excuse (2017), CESifo Working Paper Series
[6] Behnk, S.; Hao, L.; Reuben, E., Partners in crime: Diffusion of responsibility in antisocial behaviors (2017), IZA Discussion Paper
[7] Bergstrom, T., The good samaritan and traffic on the road to Jericho, Am. Econ. J. Microecon., 9, 2, 33-53 (2017)
[8] Bergstrom, T.; Garratt, R.; Leo, G., Let me, or let George? Motives of competing altruists, Games Econ. Behav., 118, 269-283 (2019) · Zbl 1429.91088
[9] Bernheim, B. D., A theory of conformity, J. Polit. Econ., 102, 5, 841-877 (1994)
[10] Bicchieri, C., The Grammar of Society: The Nature and Dynamics of Social Norms (2006), Cambridge University Press
[11] Bliss, C.; Nalebuff, B., Dragon-slaying and ballroom dancing: the private supply of a public good, J. Public Econ., 25, 1-2, 1-12 (1984)
[12] Bock, O.; Baetge, I.; Nicklisch, A., hroot: Hamburg registration and organization online tool, Eur. Econ. Rev., 71, 117-120 (2014)
[13] Bornstein, G.; Yaniv, I., Individual and group behavior in the ultimatum game: are groups more “rational” players?, Exp. Econ., 1, 1, 101-108 (1998) · Zbl 0920.90147
[14] Brennan, G.; Lomasky, L., Democracy and Decision: The Pure Theory of Electoral Preference (1997), Cambridge University Press
[15] Campos-Mercade, P., Helping behavior and group size (2018), AEA RCT Registry. June 17
[16] Campos-Mercade, P., The volunteer’s dilemma explains the bystander effect, J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 186, 646-661 (2021)
[17] Chamberlin, J., Provision of collective goods as a function of group size, Am. Polit. Sci. Rev., 68, 2, 707-716 (1974)
[18] Charness, G.; Rabin, M., Understanding social preferences with simple tests, Q. J. Econ., 117, 3, 817-869 (2002) · Zbl 1032.91710
[19] Charness, G.; Rigotti, L.; Rustichini, A., Individual behavior and group membership, Am. Econ. Rev., 97, 4, 1340-1352 (2007)
[20] Charness, G.; Sutter, M., Groups make better self-interested decisions, J. Econ. Perspect., 26, 3, 157-176 (2012)
[21] Chekroun, P.; Brauer, M., The bystander effect and social control behavior: the effect of the presence of others on people’s reactions to norm violations, Eur. J. Soc. Psychol., 32, 6, 853-867 (2002)
[22] Clark, R. D.; Word, L. E., Where is the apathetic bystander? Situational characteristics of the emergency, J. Pers. Soc. Psychol., 29, 3, 279 (1974)
[23] Cox, J. C., Trust, reciprocity, and other-regarding preferences: groups vs. individuals and males vs. females, (Experimental Business Research (2002), Springer), 331-350
[24] Cryder, C. E.; Loewenstein, G., Responsibility: the tie that binds, J. Exp. Soc. Psychol., 48, 1, 441-445 (2012)
[25] Dana, J.; Weber, R. A.; Kuang, J. X., Exploiting moral wiggle room: experiments demonstrating an illusory preference for fairness, Econ. Theory, 33, 1, 67-80 (2007) · Zbl 1121.91327
[26] Darley, J. M.; Latané, B., Bystander intervention in emergencies: diffusion of responsibility, J. Pers. Soc. Psychol., 8, 4, Pt.1, 377-383 (1968)
[27] Diekmann, A., Volunteer’s dilemma, J. Confl. Resolut., 29, 4, 605-610 (1985)
[28] Diekmann, A., Cooperation in an asymmetric volunteer’s dilemma game theory and experimental evidence, Int. J. Game Theory, 22, 1, 75-85 (1993) · Zbl 0775.90303
[29] Eckel, C. C.; Grossman, P. J., Managing diversity by creating team identity, J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 58, 3, 371-392 (2005)
[30] Falk, A.; Neuber, T.; Szech, N., Diffusion of being pivotal and immoral outcomes, Rev. Econ. Stud., 87, 5, 2205-2229 (2020)
[31] Falk, A.; Szech, N., Morals and markets, Science, 340, 6133, 707-711 (2013)
[32] Fischbacher, U., z-tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments, Exp. Econ., 10, 2, 171-178 (2007)
[33] Fischer, P.; Greitemeyer, T.; Pollozek, F.; Frey, D., The unresponsive bystander: are bystanders more responsive in dangerous emergencies?, Eur. J. Soc. Psychol., 36, 2, 267-278 (2006)
[34] Fischer, P.; Krueger, J. I.; Greitemeyer, T.; Vogrincic, C.; Kastenmüller, A.; Frey, D.; Heene, M.; Wicher, M.; Kainbacher, M., The bystander-effect: a meta-analytic review on bystander intervention in dangerous and non-dangerous emergencies, Psychol. Bull., 137, 4, 517-537 (2011)
[35] Franzen, A., Group size and one-shot collective action, Ration. Soc., 7, 2, 183-200 (1995)
[36] Fromell, H.; Nosenzo, D.; Owens, T.; Tufano, F., Are victims truly worse off in the presence of bystanders? Revisiting the bystander effect, Rev. Écon., 70, 6, 927-943 (2019)
[37] Gaertner, S. L., The role of racial attitudes in helping behavior, J. Soc. Psychol., 97, 1, 95-101 (1975)
[38] Goeree, J. K.; Holt, C. A.; Smith, A. M., An experimental examination of the volunteer’s dilemma, Games Econ. Behav., 102, 303-315 (2017) · Zbl 1409.91074
[39] Harari, H.; Harari, O.; White, R. V., The reaction to rape by American male bystanders, J. Soc. Psychol., 125, 5, 653-658 (1985)
[40] Hegstad, C. D.; Wentling, R. M., The development and maintenance of exemplary formal mentoring programs in fortune 500 companies, Hum. Resour. Dev. Q., 15, 4, 421-448 (2004)
[41] Hillenbrand, A.; Werner, T.; Winter, F., Volunteering at the workplace under incomplete information: Teamsize does not matter (2020), MPI Collective Goods Discussion Paper, (2020/4)
[42] Hillenbrand, A.; Winter, F., Volunteering under population uncertainty, Games Econ. Behav., 109, 65-81 (2018) · Zbl 1390.91091
[43] Huck, S.; Konrad, K. A., Moral cost, commitment, and committee size, J. Inst. Theor. Econ./Z. Gesamte Staatswiss., 575-588 (2005)
[44] Isaac, R. M.; Walker, J. M., Group size effects in public goods provision: the voluntary contributions mechanism, Q. J. Econ., 103, 1, 179-199 (1988)
[45] Isaac, R. M.; Walker, J. M.; Williams, A. W., Group size and the voluntary provision of public goods: experimental evidence utilizing large groups, J. Public Econ., 54, 1, 1-36 (1994)
[46] Kocher, M. G.; Schudy, S.; Spantig, L., I Lie? We lie! Why? Experimental evidence on a dishonesty shift in groups, Manag. Sci., 64, 9, 3995-4008 (2018)
[47] Latané, B.; Nida, S., Ten years of research on group size and helping, Psychol. Bull., 89, 2, 308-324 (1981)
[48] Leo, G., Taking turns, Games Econ. Behav., 102, 525-547 (2017) · Zbl 1409.91033
[49] Luhan, W. J.; Kocher, M. G.; Sutter, M., Group polarization in the team dictator game reconsidered, Exp. Econ., 12, 1, 26-41 (2009) · Zbl 1170.91326
[50] Maaser, N.; Stratmann, T., Moral cost in weighted committee decisions (2019), Working paper
[51] Near, J., Whistle-blowing: myth and reality, J. Manag., 22, 3, 507-526 (1996)
[52] Nosenzo, D.; Quercia, S.; Sefton, M., Cooperation in small groups: the effect of group size, Exp. Econ., 18, 1, 4-14 (2015)
[53] Oliver, P. E.; Marwell, G., The paradox of group size in collective action: a theory of the critical mass. ii, Am. Sociol. Rev., 1-8 (1988)
[54] Olson, M., The Logic of Collective Action (1965), Harvard University Press: Harvard University Press Cambridge
[55] Otsubo, H.; Rapoport, A., Dynamic volunteer’s dilemmas over a finite horizon, J. Confl. Resolut., 52, 6, 961-984 (2008)
[56] Palfrey, T. R.; Rosenthal, H., Participation and the provision of discrete public goods: a strategic analysis, J. Public Econ., 24, 2, 171-193 (1984)
[57] Panchanathan, K.; Frankenhuis, W. E.; Silk, J. B., The bystander effect in an n-person dictator game, Organ. Behav. Hum. Decis. Process., 120, 2, 285-297 (2013)
[58] Philpot, R.; Liebst, L. S.; Levine, M.; Bernasco, W.; Lindegaard, M. R., Would I be helped? Cross-national cctv footage shows that intervention is the norm in public conflicts, Am. Psychol., 75, 1, 66 (2020)
[59] Ross, A. S.; Braband, J., Effect of increased responsibility on bystander intervention: ii. the cue value of a blind person, J. Pers. Soc. Psychol., 25, 2, 254 (1973)
[60] Rothenhäusler, D.; Schweizer, N.; Szech, N., Guilt in voting and public good games, Eur. Econ. Rev., 101, 664-681 (2018)
[61] Shaffer, D. R.; Rogle, M.; Hendrlck, C., Intervention in the library: the effect of increased responsibility on bystanders’ willingness to prevent a theft, J. Appl. Soc. Psychol., 5, 4, 303-319 (1975)
[62] Sherman, R.; Willett, T. D., Potential entrants discourage entry, J. Polit. Econ., 75, 4, Part 1, 400-403 (1967)
[63] Shotland, R. L.; Heinold, W. D., Bystander response to arterial bleeding: helping skills, the decision-making process, and differentiating the helping response, J. Pers. Soc. Psychol., 49, 2, 347 (1985)
[64] Smith, R. E.; Smythe, L.; Lien, D., Inhibition of helping behavior by a similar or dissimilar nonreactive fellow bystander (1972)
[65] Staub, E., A child in distress: the influence of age and number of witnesses on children’s attempts to help, J. Pers. Soc. Psychol., 14, 2, 130 (1970)
[66] Van Den Bos, K.; Müller, P. A.; Van Bussel, A. A., Helping to overcome intervention inertia in bystander’s dilemmas: behavioral disinhibition can improve the greater good, J. Exp. Soc. Psychol., 45, 4, 873-878 (2009)
[67] Weesie, J., Asymmetry and timing in the volunteer’s dilemma, J. Confl. Resolut., 37, 3, 569-590 (1993)
[68] Weesie, J.; Franzen, A., Cost sharing in a volunteer’s dilemma, J. Confl. Resolut., 42, 5, 600-618 (1998)
[69] Yang, W.; Liu, W.; Viña, A.; Tuanmu, M.-N.; He, G.; Dietz, T.; Liu, J., Nonlinear effects of group size on collective action and resource outcomes, Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci., 110, 27, 10916-10921 (2013)
[70] Zhang, X. M.; Zhu, F., Group size and incentives to contribute: a natural experiment at Chinese Wikipedia, Am. Econ. Rev., 101, 4, 1601-1615 (2011)
This reference list is based on information provided by the publisher or from digital mathematics libraries. Its items are heuristically matched to zbMATH identifiers and may contain data conversion errors. In some cases that data have been complemented/enhanced by data from zbMATH Open. This attempts to reflect the references listed in the original paper as accurately as possible without claiming completeness or a perfect matching.