×

Misinterpreting others and the fragility of social learning. (English) Zbl 1466.91227

Summary: We exhibit a natural environment, social learning among heterogeneous agents, where even slight misperceptions can have a large negative impact on long-run learning outcomes. We consider a population of agents who obtain information about the state of the world both from initial private signals and by observing a random sample of other agents’ actions over time, where agents’ actions depend not only on their beliefs about the state but also on their idiosyncratic types (e.g., tastes or risk attitudes). When agents are correct about the type distribution in the population, they learn the true state in the long run. By contrast, we show, first, that even arbitrarily small amounts of misperception about the type distribution can generate extreme breakdowns of information aggregation, where in the long run all agents incorrectly assign probability 1 to some fixed state of the world, regardless of the true underlying state. Second, any misperception of the type distribution leads long-run beliefs and behavior to vary only coarsely with the state, and we provide systematic predictions for how the nature of misperception shapes these coarse long-run outcomes. Third, we show that how fragile information aggregation is against misperception depends on the richness of agents’ payoff-relevant uncertainty; a design implication is that information aggregation can be improved by simplifying agents’ learning environment. The key feature behind our findings is that agents’ belief-updating becomes “decoupled” from the true state over time. We point to other environments where this feature is present and leads to similar fragility results.

MSC:

91D15 Social learning
Full Text: DOI

References:

[1] Acemoglu, D., V.Chernozhukov, and M.Yildiz (2016): “Fragility of Asymptotic Agreement Under Bayesian Learning,” Theoretical Economics, 11 (1), 187-225. · Zbl 1395.91094
[2] Ahler, D. J. (2014): “Self‐Fulfilling Misperceptions of Public Polarization,” The Journal of Politics, 76 (3), 607-620.
[3] Ali, S. N. (2018): “Herding With Costly Information,” Journal of Economic Theory, 175, 713-729. · Zbl 1422.91457
[4] Banerjee, A. (1992): “A Simple Model of Herd Behavior,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107 (3), 797-817.
[5] Banerjee, A., and D.Fudenberg (2004): “Word‐of‐Mouth Learning,” Games and Economic Behavior, 46 (1), 1-22. · Zbl 1069.91017
[6] Berk, R. H. (1966): “Limiting Behavior of Posterior Distributions When the Model Is Incorrect,” The Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 51-58. · Zbl 0151.23802
[7] Bikhchandani, S., D.Hirshleifer, and I.Welch (1992): “A Theory of Fads, Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change as Informational Cascades,” Journal of Political Economy, 100 (5), 992-1026.
[8] Blouin, M. R., and R.Serrano (2001): “A Decentralized Market With Common Values Uncertainty: Non‐Steady States,” The Review of Economic Studies, 68 (2), 323-346. · Zbl 0980.91027
[9] Bohren, J. A. (2016): “Informational Herding With Model Misspecification,” Journal of Economic Theory, 163, 222-247. · Zbl 1369.91156
[10] Bohren, J. A., and D.Hauser (2019): “Social Learning With Model Misspecification: A Framework and a Robustness Result,” working paper.
[11] Bohren, J. A., A.Imas, and M.Rosenberg (2019): “The Dynamics of Discrimination: Theory and Evidence,” American Economic Review, 109 (10), 3395-3436.
[12] Bullock, J. G., A. S.Gerber, S. J.Hill, and G. A.Huber (2013): “Partisan Bias in Factual Beliefs About Politics,” Discussion paper, National Bureau of Economic Research.
[13] Burguet, R., and X.Vives (2000): “Social Learning and Costly Information Acquisition,” Economic Theory, 15 (1), 185-205. · Zbl 0944.91037
[14] Chamley, C. (2004): Rational Herds: Economic Models of Social Learning. Cambridge University Press.
[15] Crawford, V. P., and J.Sobel (1982): “Strategic Information Transmission,” Econometrica,50 (6), 1431-1451. · Zbl 0494.94007
[16] Dasaratha, K., and K.He (2020): “Network Structure and Naive Sequential Learning.” Theoretical Economics,15 (2), 415-444. · Zbl 1466.91225
[17] DeMarzo, P. M., D.Vayanos, and J.Zwiebel (2003): “Persuasion Bias, Social Influence, and Unidimensional Opinions,” The Quarterly journal of economics, 118 (3), 909-968. · Zbl 1069.91093
[18] Duffie, D., and G.Manso (2007): “Information Percolation in Large Markets,” American Economic Review, 97 (2), 203-209.
[19] Duffie, D., and Y.Sun (2012): “The Exact Law of Large Numbers for Independent Random Matching,” Journal of Economic Theory, 147 (3), 1105-1139. · Zbl 1258.91166
[20] Duffie, D., G.Giroux, and G.Manso (2010): “Information Percolation,” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 2 (1), 100-111.
[21] Duffie, D., S.Malamud, and G.Manso (2009): “Information Percolation With Equilibrium Search Dynamics,” Econometrica, 77 (5), 1513-1574. · Zbl 1192.91159
[22] Ellison, G., and D.Fudenberg (1993): “Rules of Thumb for Social Learning,” Journal of Political Economy, 101 (4), 612-643.
[23] Ellison, G., and D.Fudenberg (1995): “Word‐of‐Mouth Communication and Social Learning,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110 (1), 93-125. · Zbl 0827.90039
[24] Engelhardt, C., and A.Wagener (2015): “Biased Perceptions of Income Inequality and Redistribution,” mimeo.
[25] Esponda, I. (2008): “Behavioral Equilibrium in Economies With Adverse Selection,” American Economic Review, 98 (4), 1269-1291.
[26] Esponda, I., and D.Pouzo (2016): “Berk-Nash Equilibrium: A Framework for Modeling Agents With Misspecified Models,” Econometrica, 84 (3), 1093-1130. · Zbl 1419.91129
[27] Esponda, I., and D.Pouzo (2019): “Equilibrium in Misspecified Markov Decision Processes,” working paper. · Zbl 1475.91181
[28] Evans, G. W., and S.Honkapohja (2012): Learning and Expectations in Macroeconomics. Princeton University Press.
[29] Eyster, E., and M.Rabin (2010): “Naive Herding in Rich‐Information Settings,” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 2 (4), 221-243.
[30] Frick, M., R.Iijima, and Y.Ishii (2019a): “Dispersed Behavior and Perceptions in Assortative Societies,” Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper #2128.
[31] Frick, M., R.Iijima, and Y.Ishii (2019b): “Misinterpreting Others and the Fragility of Social Learning,” Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper #2160. · Zbl 1466.91227
[32] Frick, M., R.Iijima, and Y.Ishii (2019c): “Stability and Robustness in Misspecified Learning Models,” working paper.
[33] Frick, M., R.IijimaY.Ishii (2020): “Supplement to ‘Misinterpreting Others and the Fragility of Social Learning’,” Econometrica Supplemental Material, 88, https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA16981. · Zbl 1466.91227 · doi:10.3982/ECTA16981
[34] Fryer, R., and M. O.Jackson (2008): “A Categorical Model of Cognition and Biased Decision Making,” The BE Journal of Theoretical Economics,8 (1). · Zbl 1170.91324
[35] Fudenberg, D., G.Romanyuk, and P.Strack (2017): “Active Learning With a Misspecified Prior,” Theoretical Economics, 12 (3), 1155-1189. · Zbl 1396.91034
[36] Gagnon‐Bartsch, T. (2017): “Taste Projection in Models of Social Learning,” working paper.
[37] Gagnon‐Bartsch, T., and M.Rabin (2017): “Naive Social Learning, Mislearning, and Unlearning,” working paper.
[38] Glaeser, E. L., and C. R.Sunstein (2009): “Extremism and Social Learning,” Journal of Legal Analysis, 1 (1), 263-324.
[39] Goeree, J. K., T. R.Palfrey, and B. W.Rogers (2006): “Social Learning With Private and Common Values,” Economic Theory, 28 (2), 245-264. · Zbl 1107.91008
[40] Golub, B., and M. O.Jackson (2010): “Naive Learning in Social Networks and the Wisdom of Crowds,” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 2 (1), 112-149.
[41] Golub, B., and M. O.Jackson (2012): “How Homophily Affects the Speed of Learning and Best‐Response Dynamics,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127 (3), 1287-1338. · Zbl 1400.91465
[42] Guarino, A., and P.Jehiel (2013): “Social Learning With Coarse Inference,” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 5 (1), 147-174.
[43] Gul, F., W.Pesendorfer, and T.Strzalecki (2017): “Coarse Competitive Equilibrium and Extreme Prices,” American Economic Review, 107 (1), 109-137.
[44] Hassan, T. A., and T. M.Mertens (2017): “The Social Cost of Near‐Rational Investment,” American Economic Review, 107 (4), 1059-1103.
[45] Hauser, O. P., and M. I.Norton (2017): “(Mis) Perceptions of Inequality,” Current Opinion in Psychology, 18, 21-25.
[46] He, K. (2018): “Mislearning From Censored Data: The Gambler”s Fallacy in Optimal‐Stopping Problems,” working paper.
[47] Heidhues, P., B.Koszegi, and P.Strack (2018): “Unrealistic Expectations and Misguided Learning,” Econometrica, 86 (4), 1159-1214. · Zbl 1396.91084
[48] Heidhues, P., B.Koszegi, and P.Strack (2019): “Convergence in Misspecified Learning Models With Endogenous Actions,” Available at SSRN 3312968.
[49] Jehiel, P. (2005): “Analogy‐Based Expectation Equilibrium,” Journal of Economic theory, 123 (2), 81-104. · Zbl 1102.91014
[50] Jehiel, P. (2018): “Investment Strategy and Selection Bias: An Equilibrium Perspective on Overoptimism,” American Economic Review,108 (6), 1582-1597.
[51] Kunda, Z. (1999): Social Cognition: Making Sense of People. MIT press.
[52] Lee, I. H. (1993): “On the Convergence of Informational Cascades,” Journal of Economic Theory, 61 (2), 395-411. · Zbl 0796.90012
[53] Levy, G., and R.Razin (2015): “Correlation Neglect, Voting Behavior, and Information Aggregation,” American Economic Review, 105 (4), 1634-1645.
[54] Madarász, K., and A.Prat (2017): “Sellers With Misspecified Models,” The Review of Economic Studies, 84 (2), 790-815. · Zbl 1405.91208
[55] Mayzlin, D., Y.Dover, and J.Chevalier (2014): “Promotional Reviews: An Empirical Investigation of Online Review Manipulation,” American Economic Review, 104 (8), 2421-2455.
[56] Morris, S., and H. S.Shin (2002): “Social Value of Public Information,” American Economic Review, 92 (5), 1521-1534.
[57] Mossel, E., A.Sly, and O.Tamuz (2015): “Strategic Learning and the Topology of Social Networks,” Econometrica, 83 (5), 1755-1794. · Zbl 1419.91561
[58] Mueller‐Frank, M. (2018): “Manipulating Opinions in Social Networks,” working paper.
[59] Mullainathan, S. (2002): “Thinking Through Categories,” working paper.
[60] Myatt, D. P., and C.Wallace (2014): “Central Bank Communication Design in a Lucas‐Phelps Economy,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 63, 64-79.
[61] Nisbett, R. E., and Z.Kunda (1985): “Perception of Social Distributions,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 48 (2), 297.
[62] Norton, M. I., and D.Ariely (2011): “Building a Better America-One Wealth Quintile at a Time,” Perspectives on Psychological Science, 6 (1), 9-12.
[63] Nyarko, Y. (1991): “Learning in mis‐Specified Models and the Possibility of Cycles,” Journal of Economic Theory, 55 (2), 416-427. · Zbl 0742.90021
[64] Ortoleva, P., and E.Snowberg (2015): “Overconfidence in Political Behavior,” American Economic Review, 105 (2), 504-535.
[65] Rabin, M. (2002): “Inference by Believers in the Law of Small Numbers,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117 (3), 775-816. · Zbl 1021.91051
[66] Rabin, M., and D.Vayanos (2010): “The Gambler”s and Hot‐Hand Fallacies: Theory and Applications,” The Review of Economic Studies, 77 (2), 730-778. · Zbl 1297.91043
[67] Reis, R. (2006a): “Inattentive Consumers,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 53 (8), 1761-1800.
[68] Reis, R. (2006b): “Inattentive Producers,” The Review of Economic Studies, 73 (3), 793-821. · Zbl 1145.91361
[69] Ross, L., D.Greene, and P.House (1977): “The “False Consensus Effect:” an Egocentric Bias in Social Perception and Attribution Processes,” Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 13 (3), 279-301.
[70] Shaked, M., and G.Shanthikumar (2007): Stochastic Orders. Springer. · Zbl 1111.62016
[71] Sims, C. A. (1998): “Stickiness,” in Carnegie‐Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 49. Elsevier, 317-356.
[72] Sims, C. A. (2003): “Implications of Rational Inattention,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 50 (3), 665-690.
[73] Smith, L., and P.Sørensen (2000): “Pathological Outcomes of Observational Learning,” Econometrica, 68 (2), 371-398. · Zbl 1023.91510
[74] Spiegler, R. (2016): “Bayesian Networks and Boundedly Rational Expectations,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 131 (3), 1243-1290. · Zbl 1400.91146
[75] Stroock, D. W. (2010): Probability Theory: An Analytic View. Cambridge University Press.
[76] Sun, Y. (2006): “The Exact Law of Large Numbers via Fubini Extension and Characterization of Insurable Risks,” Journal of Economic Theory, 126 (1), 31-69. · Zbl 1108.60025
[77] Vives, X. (1993): “How Fast Do Rational Agents Learn?” The Review of Economic Studies, 60 (2), 329-347. · Zbl 0774.90019
[78] Vives, X. (2010): Information and Learning in Markets: The Impact of Market Microstructure. Princeton University Press.
[79] Wolinsky, A. (1990): “Information Revelation in a Market With Pairwise Meetings,” Econometrica,58 (1), 1-23. · Zbl 0728.90022
This reference list is based on information provided by the publisher or from digital mathematics libraries. Its items are heuristically matched to zbMATH identifiers and may contain data conversion errors. In some cases that data have been complemented/enhanced by data from zbMATH Open. This attempts to reflect the references listed in the original paper as accurately as possible without claiming completeness or a perfect matching.