×

Advertising cycling to manage exclusivity loss in fashion styles. (English) Zbl 1505.90076

Summary: This paper uses dynamic optimization to study the optimal advertising of fashion products over time. For fashion products, brand advertising and exclusivity are important sales drivers. Therefore, we propose a dynamic model of the sales of multiple styles of a fashion brand based on these variables. The model is estimated using a particle filter method on data from two fashion categories (handbags and sunglasses) and has good fit and prediction. We also derive explicit analytical solutions of the optimal, closed-loop advertising control and use it to explain advertising and fashion cycles. A managerial prescription is that advertising cycling should be out of phase with sales, for example, trend down when fashion sales is trending up. Thus, advertising flattens the fashion sales cycle over time rather than reinforcing it.

MSC:

90B60 Marketing, advertising
90C39 Dynamic programming
Full Text: DOI

References:

[1] Appel G, Libai B, Muller E (2018) On the monetary impact of fashion design piracy. Internat. J. Res. Marketing 35(4):591-610.Crossref, Google Scholar · doi:10.1016/j.ijresmar.2018.08.003
[2] Aravindakshan A, Naik PA (2015) Understanding the memory effects in pulsing advertising. Oper. Res. 63(1):35-47.Link, Google Scholar · Zbl 1377.90050
[3] Balachander S, Stock A (2009) Limited edition products: When and when not to offer them. Marketing Sci. 28(2):336-355.Link, Google Scholar
[4] Bass FM (1969) A new product growth model for consumer durables. Management Sci. 15(5):215-227.Link, Google Scholar · Zbl 1231.91323
[5] Bass FM, Krishnamoorthy A, Prasad A, Sethi SP (2005) Generic and brand advertising strategies in a dynamic duopoly. Marketing Sci. 24(4):556-568.Link, Google Scholar
[6] Bass FM, Bruce NI, Majumdar S, Murthi BPS (2007) Wearout effects of different advertising themes: A dynamic Bayesian model of advertising-sales relationship. Marketing Sci. 26(2):179-195.Link, Google Scholar
[7] Bruce NI (2008) Pooling and dynamic forgetting effects in multi-theme advertising: Tracking the ad sales relationship with particle filters. Marketing Sci. 27(4):659-673.Link, Google Scholar
[8] Bruce NI (2019) Nonparametric Bayesian dynamic methods: Applications to linear and nonlinear advertising models. J. Marketing Res. 56(2):210-229.Crossref, Google Scholar · doi:10.1177/0022243718810524
[9] Bruce NI, Becker M, Reinartz W (2020) Communicating brands in television advertising. J. Marketing Res. 57(2):236-256.Crossref, Google Scholar · doi:10.1177/0022243719892576
[10] Cachon GP, Swinney R (2011) The value of fast fashion: Quick response, enhanced design, and strategic consumer behavior. Management Sci. 57(4):778-795.Link, Google Scholar · Zbl 1214.90070
[11] Caro F, Gallien J (2010) Inventory management of a fast-fashion retail network. Oper. Res. 58(2):257-273.Link, Google Scholar · Zbl 1233.90218
[12] Caro F, Gallien J (2012) Clearance pricing optimization for a fast-fashion retailer. Oper. Res. 60(6):1404-1422.Link, Google Scholar · Zbl 1262.91063
[13] Caulkins JP, Hartl RF, Kort PM, Feichtinger G (2007) Explaining fashion cycles: Imitators chasing innovators in product space. J. Econom. Dynam. Control 31(5):1535-1556.Crossref, Google Scholar · Zbl 1201.91146 · doi:10.1016/j.jedc.2006.05.008
[14] Chintagunta PK, Jain DC (1995) Empirical analysis of a dynamic duopoly model of competition. J. Econom. Management Strategy 4(1):109-131.Crossref, Google Scholar · doi:10.1111/j.1430-9134.1995.00109.x
[15] Coelho P, McClure J (1993) Toward an economic theory of fashion. Econom. Inquiry 31(4):595-608.Crossref, Google Scholar · doi:10.1111/j.1465-7295.1993.tb00893.x
[16] Corneo G, Jeanne O (1997) Conspicuous consumption, snobbism and conformism. J. Public Econom. 66(1):55-71.Crossref, Google Scholar · doi:10.1016/S0047-2727(97)00016-9
[17] Di Giovinazzo V, Naimzada A (2015) A model of fashion: Endogenous preferences in social interaction. Econom. Model. 47:12-17.Crossref, Google Scholar · doi:10.1016/j.econmod.2014.12.029
[18] Doucet A, Nando dF, Gordon N, eds. (2001) Sequential Monte Carlo Methods in Practice (Springer, New York).Crossref, Google Scholar · Zbl 0967.00022 · doi:10.1007/978-1-4757-3437-9
[19] Erickson GM (2009) Advertising competition in a dynamic oligopoly with multiple brands. Oper. Res. 57(5):1106-1113.Link, Google Scholar · Zbl 1233.91182
[20] Ertekin ZO, Atik D (2015) Sustainable markets: Motivating factors, barriers, and remedies for mobilization of slow fashion. J. Macromarketing 35(1):53-69.Crossref, Google Scholar · doi:10.1177/0276146714535932
[21] Fletcher K (2010) Slow fashion: An invitation for systems change. Fashion Practice: J. Design Creative Process Fashion Industry 2(2):259-266.Google Scholar
[22] Freimer M, Horsky D (2012) Periodic advertising pulsing in a competitive market. Marketing Sci. 31(4):637-648.Link, Google Scholar
[23] Fruchter G, Prasad A, Van den Bulte C (2022) Too popular, too fast: Optimal advertising and entry timing in markets with peer influence. Management Sci. 68(6):4725-4741.Link, Google Scholar
[24] Godsill S, Doucet A, West M (2004) Monte Carlo smoothing for nonlinear time series. J. Amer. Statist. Assoc. 99(465):156-168.Crossref, Google Scholar · Zbl 1089.62517 · doi:10.1198/016214504000000151
[25] Hennigs N, Wiedmann K-P, Behrens S, Klarmann C (2013) Unleashing the power of luxury: Antecedents of luxury brand perception and effects on luxury brand strength. J. Brand Management 20(8):705-715.Crossref, Google Scholar · doi:10.1057/bm.2013.11
[26] Hitsch GJ, Hortacsu A, Lin X (2019). Prices and promotions in U.S. retail markets. Preprint, submitted September 27, https://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3459755.Google Scholar
[27] Leibenstein H (1950) Bandwagon, snob and Veblen effects in the theory of consumers’ demand. Quart. J. Econom. 64(2):183-207.Crossref, Google Scholar · doi:10.2307/1882692
[28] Little JDC (1979) Aggregate advertising models: The state of the art. Oper. Res. 27(4):629-854.Link, Google Scholar · Zbl 0412.90037
[29] Liu JS, Chen R (1998) Sequential Monte Carlo methods for dynamic systems. J. Amer. Statist. Assoc. 93(443):1032-1043.Crossref, Google Scholar · Zbl 1064.65500 · doi:10.1080/01621459.1998.10473765
[30] Mesak HI, Bari A, Lian Q (2015) Pulsation in a competitive model of advertising-firm’s cost interaction. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 246(3):916-926.Crossref, Google Scholar · Zbl 1346.90465 · doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2015.04.052
[31] Naik PA, Mantrala MK, Sawyer AG (1998) Planning media schedules in the presence of dynamic advertising quality. Marketing Sci. 17(3):214-235.Link, Google Scholar
[32] Naik PA, Prasad A, Sethi SP (2008) Building brand awareness in dynamic oligopoly markets. Management Sci. 54(1):129-138.Link, Google Scholar · Zbl 1142.91647
[33] Nerlove M, Arrow KJ (1962) Optimal advertising policy under dynamic conditions. Economica 29(114):129-142.Crossref, Google Scholar · doi:10.2307/2551549
[34] Nunez JA, Singham DI, Atkinson MP (2019) A particle filter approach to estimating target location using Brownian motion. J. Oper. Res. Soc. 71(4):589-605.Crossref, Google Scholar · doi:10.1080/01605682.2019.1570806
[35] Pashigian BP (1988) Demand uncertainty and sales: A study of fashion and markdown pricing. Amer. Econom. Rev. 78(5):936-953.Google Scholar
[36] Pesendorfer W (1995) Design innovation and fashion cycles. Amer. Econom. Rev. 85(4):771-792.Google Scholar
[37] Pigou A (1903) Some remarks on utility. Econom. J. (London) 13(49):58-68.Google Scholar
[38] Prasad A, Sethi SP (2004) Competitive advertising under uncertainty: A stochastic differential game approach. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 123(1):163-185.Crossref, Google Scholar · Zbl 1114.90050 · doi:10.1023/B:JOTA.0000043996.62867.20
[39] Ristic B, Arulampalam S, Gordon N (2004) Beyond the Kalman Filter: Particle Filters for Tracking Applications (Artech House, Boston).Google Scholar · Zbl 1092.93041
[40] Sasieni MW (1971) Optimal advertising expenditures. Management Sci. 18(4):64-72.Link, Google Scholar
[41] Sethi SP (1973) Optimal control of the Vidale-Wolfe advertising model. Oper. Res. 21(4):998-1013.Link, Google Scholar · Zbl 0278.49007
[42] Sethi SP (1983) Deterministic and stochastic optimization of a dynamic advertising model. Optimal Control Appl. Methods 4(2):179-184.Crossref, Google Scholar · Zbl 0505.93081 · doi:10.1002/oca.4660040207
[43] Sethi SP, Prasad A, He X (2008) Optimal advertising and pricing in a new-product adoption model. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 139(2):351-360.Crossref, Google Scholar · Zbl 1159.49035 · doi:10.1007/s10957-008-9472-5
[44] Sethuraman R, Tellis GJ, Briesch RA (2011) How well does advertising work? Generalizations from meta-analysis of brand advertising elasticities. J. Marketing Res. 48(3):457-471.Crossref, Google Scholar · doi:10.1509/jmkr.48.3.457
[45] Simmel G (1957) Fashion. Amer. J. Sociol. 62(6):541-558.Crossref, Google Scholar · doi:10.1086/222102
[46] Sorger G (1989) Competitive dynamic advertising: A modification of the Case game. J. Econom. Dynam. Control 13(1):55-80.Crossref, Google Scholar · Zbl 0657.90031 · doi:10.1016/0165-1889(89)90011-0
[47] Veblen T (1934) The Theory of the Leisure Class (Random House, New York).Google Scholar
[48] Vidale ML, Wolfe HB (1957) An operations research study of sales response to advertising. Oper. Res. 5(3):370-381.Link, Google Scholar · Zbl 1414.90186
[49] Wu L, Lee C (2016) Limited edition for me and best seller for you: The impact of scarcity versus popularity cues on self versus other-purchase behavior. J. Retailing 92(4):486-499.Google Scholar
[50] Yoganarasimhan H (2017) Identifying the presence and cause of fashion cycles in data. J. Marketing Res. 54(1):5-26.Crossref, Google Scholar · doi:10.1509/jmr.15.0119
[51] Zhang B, Cao Z, Qin C-Z, Yang X (2018) Fashion and homophily. Oper. Res. 66(6):1486-1497.Link, Google Scholar · Zbl 1455.91059
This reference list is based on information provided by the publisher or from digital mathematics libraries. Its items are heuristically matched to zbMATH identifiers and may contain data conversion errors. In some cases that data have been complemented/enhanced by data from zbMATH Open. This attempts to reflect the references listed in the original paper as accurately as possible without claiming completeness or a perfect matching.