Skip to main content
Log in

Valuing publicly sponsored research projects: Risks, scenario adjustments, and inattention

  • Published:
Journal of Risk and Uncertainty Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Survey-based choice scenarios used to value non-market public goods typically preclude any risk that the benefits described may not be delivered. Our survey specifies explicit risks of (a) outright program failure and (b) program redundancy due to possible private sector substitutes. Additionally, most analyses assume that survey subjects fully accept these scenarios and that all provided information receives their complete attention. Our discounted expected utility model of choice accommodates both these objective risks and the possibility of subjective scenario adjustment or selective inattention by respondents. We then counterfactually simulate willingness-to-pay in the absence of these distortions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Risks of failure and substitution are not typically included as attributes of the good under study. Additional uncertainty concerns how severe changes in climate may turn out to be. This point is addressed below.

  2. Krupnick and Adamowicz (2007) note that a “surprisingly large number of [stated choice] surveys do not use debriefing questions” (p. 53). They advise against the use of debriefing questions which force respondents to answer either yes or no, and suggest that it is preferable to offer a range of responses. This information can then be “used in validity regressions.” However, they suggest that such variables “are best left out of the final regression, however, because of endogeneity concerns. If such responses are not too numerous they can be dropped” (p. 54).

  3. We note that while we have information about the amount of time each respondent spent on this one page of our internet survey, respondents may have different cognitive abilities, so that the same amount of “attention” could map into different amounts of survey time for different respondents.

  4. The data used here were collected in the Fall of 2001 and consist of 14,071 choices by 2,003 respondents. The survey is still accessible for use as a pedagogical tool (but does not record choices).

  5. We vary the manner in which the question is posed to the respondent because stated choice experiments are often subject to the criticism that the choices elicited from respondents are merely an artifact of the format and framing of questions. By randomizing the format and framing of choices in our survey, we are able to assess the sensitivity of our results to these different scenario design decisions. In many earlier surveys, just one design would be selected, which precludes this type of sensitivity analysis.

  6. If we were to repeat this survey experiment, we would certainly expand this choice scenario to be explicit about the provision mechanism. Given the data that we have to work with, we can only assume that respondents made their choices with an understanding that the government-sponsored research program would be put into action if aggregate “check-off” amounts reached some goal and that if the total was not sufficient, there would be no program (and the “checked-off” amount would be rebated as a tax credit).

  7. Amato et al. (2005), Hor et al. (2005), Mansur et al. (2005), and Sailor (2001) examine air conditioner technologies generally. Curriero et al. (2002), Davis et al. (2002), Davis et al. (2003), McGeehin and Mirabelli (2001), and Yoganathan and Rom (2001) focus on the role air conditioners play in mitigating the effects of extreme weather events.

  8. Bonte (2004), Griliches (1992), Jaffe (2002), Jones and Williams (1998), Mamuneas (1999), and Popp (2006) examine the spillovers associated with research and development projects. Griffith et al. (2001) consider tax credits to firms to promote R&D, rather than withholding tax credits to households in order to sponsor R&D.

  9. See for example Clark et al. (2003), Goeree et al. (2002), and Nunes and Schokkaert (2003).

  10. The online survey was programmed in Perl and made liberal use of the FastTemplate utility. Table O-1, in the online Appendix O, contains detailed summary statistics for these randomized choice framing differences. Appendix O can be found at http://www.uoregon.edu/~cameron/JRU/BCG_Appendix.pdf

  11. Subjective risks have been considered in other contexts (e.g. DeShazo and Cameron 2005, and Viscusi and Huber 2006). Unfortunately, we are not able to conduct this interesting comparison with these data.

  12. This was a highly complex survey and we are grateful for the huge amount of time, individually and in the aggregate, that participating individuals contributed to this research program.

  13. For this formulation we do not consider more flexible discounting formulae because benefits will accrue, at the earliest, in 5 years. See Frederick, Loewenstein and O’Donoghue (2002) and Laibson (1997).

  14. It is possible that the effort dedicated to similar research in the private sector may depend on whether a government-sponsored research program is under way. We abstract from any such dependence in this analysis. It proved too difficult to attempt to explain more-complex probabilities to survey respondents.

  15. There is also some chance that respondents may overreact by assuming that the probability of failure is greater than advertised. Our estimating specification does not preclude this possible outcome.

  16. This product cannot, technically, be interpreted as a subjective probability. If this was our aim, then these “subjectively adjusted” probabilities would have to be constrained as valid probabilities (i.e. lie between zero and one). However, we do not put such constraints on these parameters theoretically or during estimation. To attempt a formal Bayesian updating model, of course, we would need additional information about respondents’ prior probabilities.

  17. The government program can thus be viewed as a measure designed to increase the probability of a desirable outcome, namely, the technology being developed one way or the other.

  18. We have also explored specifications in which utility parameters vary systematically with observable respondent characteristics with no change in the qualitative results that are the focus of this paper.

  19. Note that these designations are completely arbitrary and have no effect on our results.

  20. Other researchers have called these types of data a “multiple-bounded” elicitation format (e.g. see Welsh and Poe 1998). Different interpretations of these responses are possible, but we use the ordered-logit interpretation employed in Cameron et al. (2002).

  21. Since standard packaged algorithms are not available for models that aggregate ordered data across sub-samples with differing numbers of answer categories, this likelihood function must be programmed in MATLAB (or some other generic function-optimizing software).

  22. In future research, we may consider in more depth the effects of allowing the randomized differences in survey formats also to shift each of the three basic utility parameters, not just the error dispersion parameter (which is the model we report here). If we simultaneously generalize all the utility and dispersion parameters to allow for these format effects, many individually statistically significant effects are obscured by this over-parameterization. It is clear that this heterogeneity matters, but we have not yet undertaken rigorous non-nested tests of just where it is best to accommodate it. The answer may differ across applications, so the question may be complex enough to warrant an entirely separate analysis.

  23. For example, individuals may be paternalistically altruistic or anticipate spillovers from the new technologies.

  24. Table O-1 in the online Appendix O details the distributions for the independent dynamically generated choice scenario attributes. For simplicity, we round these approximate means.

  25. This valuable connection was suggested by a referee. Also, in the CV literature, Carson et al. (1997) characterized ancillary conditions as “circumstances of choice.”

References

  • Adamowicz, Wiktor, Joffre Swait, Peter Boxall, Jordan Louviere, and Michael Williams. (1997). “Perceptions Versus Objective Measures of Environmental Quality in Combined Revealed and Stated Preference Models of Environmental Valuation,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 32(1), 65–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amato, Anthony D., Matthias Ruth, Paul Kirshen, and James Horwitz. (2005). “Regional Energy Demand Responses to Climate Change: Methodology and Application to the Commonwealth of Massachusetts,” Climatic Change 71(1), 175–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, Kenneth J., Robert M. Solow, Paul R. Portney, Edward E. Leamer, Roy Radner, and Howard Schuman. (1993). “Report of the NOAA Blue Ribbon Panel on Contingent Valuation,” Federal Register 58, 4601–4614.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim, B. Douglas and Antonio Rangel. (2004). “Addiction and Cue-Triggered Decision Processes,” American Economic Review 94(5), 1558–1590.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim, Douglas B. and Antonio Rangel. (2007). “Toward Choice-Theoretic Foundations for Behavioral Welfare Economics,” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 97(2), 464–470.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berrens, Robert P., Alok K. Bohara, Hank C. Jenkins-Smith, Carol L. Silva, and David L. Weimer. (2004). “Information and Effort in Contingent Valuation Surveys: Application to Global Climate Change Using National Internet Samples,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 47(2), 331–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonte, Werner. (2004). “Spillovers from Publicly Financed Business R&D: Some Empirical Evidence from Germany,” Research Policy 33(10), 1635–1655.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyle, Kevin. (2003). “Contingent Valuation in Practice.” In Patricia Champ, Kevin J. Boyle, and Thomas C. Brown (eds.). A Primer on Nonmarket Valuation. Boston, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cameron, Trudy Ann, J. R. DeShazo, and Erica H. Johnson. (2007). “Scenario Adjustment in Stated Preference Research.” In American Agricultural Economics Association Annual Meeting, Portland, OR.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cameron, Trudy Ann, Gregory L. Poe, Robert G. Ethier, and William D. Schulze. (2002). “Alternative Non-Market Value-Elicitation Methods: Are the Underlying Preferences the Same?” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 44(3), 391–425.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carson, Richard T., W. Michael Hanemann, Raymond J. Kopp, Jon A. Krosnick, Robert C. Mitchell, Stanley Presser, Paul A. Ruud, V. Kerry Smith, Michael Conaway, and Kerry Martin. (1997). “Temporal Reliability of Estimates from Contingent Valuation,” Land Economics 73(2), 151–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, Christopher F., Matthew J. Kotchen, Michael R. Moore. (2003). “Internal and External Influences on Pro-Environmental Behavior: Participation in a Green Electricity Program,” Journal of Environmental Psychology 23(3), 237–246.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Curriero, Frank C., Karlyn S. Heiner, Jonathan M. Samet, Scott L. Zeger, Lisa Strug, and Jonathan A. Patz. (2002). “Temperature and Mortality in 11 Cities of the Eastern United States,” American Journal of Epidemiology 155(1), 80–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, Robert E., Paul C. Knappenberger, Patrick J. Michaels, and Wendy M. Novicoff. (2003). “Changing Heat-Related Mortality in the United States,” Environmental Health Perspectives 111(14), 1712–1718.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, Robert E., Paul C. Knappenberger, Wendy M. Novicoff, and Patrick J. Michaels. (2002). “Decadal Changes in Heat-Related Human Mortality in the Eastern United States,” Climate Research 22(2), 175–184.

    Google Scholar 

  • DeShazo, J. R. and Trudy Ann Cameron. (2005). “The Effect of Health Status on Willingness to Pay for Morbidity and Mortality Risk Reductions.” Department of Economics Working Paper, University of Oregon. Eugene, OR. 61 pp.

  • DeShazo, J. R. and German Fermo. (2002). “Designing Choice Sets for Stated Preference Methods: The Effects of Complexity on Choice Consistency,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 44(1), 123–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frederick, Shane, George Loewenstein, and Ted O’Donoghue. (2002). “Time Discounting and Time Preference: A Critical Review,” Journal of Economic Literature 40(2), 351–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gabaix, Xavier, David Laibson, Guillermo Moloche, and Stephen Weinberg. (2006). “Costly Information Acquisition: Experimental Analysis of a Boundedly Rational Model,” American Economic Review 96(4), 1043–1068.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goeree, Jacob K., Charles A. Holt, and Susan K. Laury. (2002). “Private Costs and Public Benefits: Unraveling the Effects of Altruism and Noisy Behavior,” Journal of Public Economics 83(2), 255–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griffith, Rachel, Stephen Redding, and John Van Reenen. (2001). “Measuring the Cost-Effectiveness of an R&D Tax Credit for the UK,” Fiscal Studies 22(3), 375–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Zvi. (1992). “The Search for Research-and-Development Spillovers,” Scandinavian Journal of Economics 94, S29–S47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hor, Ching-Lai, Simon J. Watson, and Shanti Majithia. (2005). “Analyzing the Impact of Weather Variables on Monthly Electricity Demand,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems 20(4), 2078–2085.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe, Adam B. (2002). “Building Programme Evaluation into the Design of Public Research-Support Programmes,” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 18(1), 22–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, F. Reed and William H. Desvousges. (1997). “Estimating Stated Preferences with Rated-Pair Data: Environmental, Health, and Employment Effects of Energy Programs,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 34(1), 79–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, Charles I. and John C. Williams. (1998). “Measuring the Social Return to R&D,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 113(4), 1119–1135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krupnick, Alan and Wiktor L. Adamowicz. (2007). “Supporting Questions in Stated Choice Studies.” In Barbara J. Kanninen (ed.), Valuing Environmental Amenities Using Stated Choice Studies. Dordrecht, The Netherlands: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laibson, David. (1997). “Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(2), 443–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mamuneas, Theofanis P. (1999). “Spillovers from Publicly Financed R&D Capital in High-Tech Industries,” International Journal of Industrial Organization 17(2), 215–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansur, Erin T., Robert Mendelsohn, and Wendy Morrison. (2005). “A Discrete–Continuous Choice Model of Climate Change Impacts on Energy.” New Haven, CT: Yale School of Management, mimeo. pp. 1–41.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGeehin, Michael A. and Maria Mirabelli. (2001). “The Potential Impacts of Climate Variability and Change on Temperature-Related Morbidity and Mortality in the United States,” Environmental Health Perspectives 109, 185–189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nunes, Paulo and Erik Schokkaert. (2003). “Identifying the Warm Glow Effect in Contingent Valuation,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 45(2), 231–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poor, P. Joan, Kevin J. Boyle, Laura O. Taylor, and Roy Bouchard. (2001). “Objective Versus Subjective Measures of Water Clarity in Hedonic Property Value Models,” Land Economics 77(4), 482–493.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Popp, D. (2006). “R&D Subsidies and Climate Policy: Is There a “Free Lunch?” Climatic Change 77(3–4), 311–341.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saelensminde, Kjartan. (2002). “The Impact of Choice Inconsistencies in Stated Choice Studies,” Environmental & Resource Economics 23(4), 403–420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sailor, David J. (2001). “Relating Residential and Commercial Sector Electricity Loads to Climate—Evaluating State Level Sensitivities and Vulnerabilities,” Energy 26(7), 645–657.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. Kerry and William H. Desvousges. (1990). “Risk Communication and the Value of Information—Radon as a Case-Study,” Review of Economics and Statistics 72(1), 137–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. Kip and Joel C. Huber. (2006). “Hyperbolic Discounting of Public Goods,” NBER Working Paper No. W11935. Available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=876038.

  • Welsh, Michael P. and Gregory L. Poe. (1998). “Elicitation Effects in Contingent Valuation: Comparisons to a Multiple Bounded Discrete Choice Approach,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 36(2), 170–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yoganathan, Dushana and William N. Rom. (2001). “Medical Aspects of Global Warming,” American Journal of Industrial Medicine 40(2), 199–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The data for this study were collected with funding from the National Science Foundation (SES-9818875). The research was supported in part by a Kleinsorge Summer Fellowship and by the endowment of the R.F. Mikesell Chair in Environmental and Resource Economics at the University of Oregon. We are grateful to Vilija Gulbinas for assistance with survey development and implementation at UCLA, to Paul Jakus and participants at the 2006 W1133 and OREE meetings, Nino Sitchinava, and our referees for helpful comments, and to Ian McConnaha and Tatiana Raterman for research assistance at the University of Oregon. We are also grateful for the very generous cooperation of 114 instructors at 92 different colleges and universities in the US and Canada who announced our survey to their classes and encouraged participation. The opinions expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the opinions of the Federal Reserve Board of Governors or its staff. Any remaining errors are our own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Trudy Ann Cameron.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Log-likelihood function

Each different answer format offered on the survey implies a different set of ordered-logit probability formulas. These probabilities, by number of answer levels, are as follows:

2-level: \( \begin{array}{*{20}l} {{{\text{P2}}Y_{i} = \frac{1} {{1 + \exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{20}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{20}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}}\quad {\text{YES}}} \hfill} \\ {{{\text{P2}}N_{i} = \frac{{\exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{20}} - \Delta V} \right)}_{i} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{20}} - \Delta V} \right)}_{i} } {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}} {{1 + \exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{20}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{20}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}}\quad {\text{NO}}} \hfill} \\ \end{array} \)

3-level: \( \begin{array}{*{20}c} {{\text{P3}}Y_{i} = \frac{1} {{1 + \exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{31}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{31}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}}}{YES} \\ {{\text{P3}}M_{i} = {\left( {\frac{{\exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{31}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{31}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}} {{1 + \exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{31}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{31}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}}} \right)} - {\left( {\frac{{\exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{30}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{30}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}} {{1 + \exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{30}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{30}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}}} \right)}}{NOT\;SURE} \\ {{\text{P3}}N_{i} = \frac{{\exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{30}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{30}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}} {{1 + \exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{30}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{30}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}}}{NO} \\ \end{array} \)

4-level: \( \begin{array}{*{20}l} {{{\text{P}}4{\text{D}}Y_{i} = \frac{1} {{1 + \exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{42}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{42}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}}\quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad {\text{Def}}{\text{.}}\;{\text{YES}}} \hfill} \\ {{{\text{P}}4{\text{P}}Y_{i} = {\left( {\frac{{\exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{42}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{42}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}} {{1 + \exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{42}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{42}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}}} \right)} - {\left( {\frac{{\exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{41}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{41}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}} {{1 + \exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{41}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{41}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}}} \right)}\quad \quad \Pr {\text{ob}}{\text{. YES}}} \hfill} \\ {{{\text{P}}4{\text{P}}N_{i} = {\left( {\frac{{\exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{41}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{41}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}} {{1 + \exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{41}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{41}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}}} \right)} - {\left( {\frac{{\exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{40}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{40}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}} {{1 + \exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{40}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{40}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}}} \right)}\quad \quad \Pr {\text{ob}}{\text{.}}\;{\text{NO}}} \hfill} \\ {{P4DN = \frac{{\exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{40}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{40}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}} {{1 + \exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{40}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{40}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}}\quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad {\text{Def}}{\text{.}}\;{\text{NO}}} \hfill} \\ \end{array} \)

5-level: \( \begin{array}{*{20}l} {{{\text{P5D}}Y_{i} = \frac{1} {{1 + \exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{53}} - \Delta V_{1} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{53}} - \Delta V_{1} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}}} \hfill} & {{{\text{Def}}{\text{.}}\;{\text{YES}}} \hfill} \\ {{{\text{P5P}}Y_{i} = {\left( {\frac{{\exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{53}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{53}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}} {{1 + \exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{53}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{53}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}}} \right)} - {\left( {\frac{{\exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{52}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{52}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}} {{1 + \exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{52}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{52}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}}} \right)}} \hfill} & {{\Pr {\text{ob}}{\text{.}}\;{\text{YES}}} \hfill} \\ {{{\text{P}}5M_{i} = {\left( {\frac{{\exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{52}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{52}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}} {{1 + \exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{52}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{52}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}}} \right)} - {\left( {\frac{{\exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{51}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{51}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}} {{1 + \exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{51}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{51}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}}} \right)}} \hfill} & {{{\text{NOT}}\;{\text{SURE}}} \hfill} \\ {{P5PN_{i} = {\left( {\frac{{\exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{51}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{51}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}} {{1 + \exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{51}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{51}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}}} \right)} - {\left( {\frac{{\exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{50}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{50}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}} {{1 + \exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{50}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{50}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}}} \right)}} \hfill} & {{{\text{Prob}}{\text{.}}\;{\text{NO}}} \hfill} \\ {{P5DN_{i} = {\left( {\frac{{\exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{50}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{50}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}} {{1 + \exp {\left[ {{{\left( {\alpha _{{50}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\alpha _{{50}} - \Delta V_{i} } \right)}} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\exp {\left( {\kappa _{i} } \right)}}} \right]}}}} \right)}} \hfill} & {{{\text{Def}}{\text{.}}\;{\text{NO}}} \hfill} \\ \end{array} \)

A little extra intuition is involved when pooling data from two-, three-, four-, and five-alternative simple or ordered logit specification. In a two-outcome model, it is natural to normalize the threshold level of the latent variable, α 20 above, to zero. When pooling all four types of data, it makes sense to normalize the distinction between a “yes” answer and a “no” answer to zero. For the three- and five-outcome cases, however, there is no bright line between “yes” and “no,” due to the presence of the “not sure” option. Thus we normalize α 20 and α 41 to zero, but allow all of the other thresholds (α 30, α 31, α 40, α 42, and α 50, α 51, α 52, and α 53) to take on whatever values the data seem to dictate, with the expectation that α 30, α 40, α 50, and α 51 should be negative and the others should be positive.

1.2 Log-likelihood function

Denote the number of observations in each sub-sample with 2, 3, 4, and 5 answer options as N2, N3, N4 and N5. The formula for the log-likelihood function, as always, involves discrete indicators for each answer option. All of the following binary indicators are “zero otherwise”:

  • C2Y i , C3Y i = 1 if respondent chooses “yes” in 2- or 3- alternative cases

  • C2N i , C3N i =1 if respondent chooses “no” in 2- or 3-alternative cases

  • C3M i , C5M i =1 if respondent chooses “not sure” in 3- or 5-alternative cases

  • C4DY i , C5DY i =1 if respondent chooses “definitely yes” in 4- or 5-alternative cases

  • C4PY i , C5PY i =1 if respondent chooses “probably yes” in 4- or 5-alternative cases

  • C4PN i , C5PN i =1 if respondent chooses “probably no” in 4- or 5-alternative cases

  • C4DN i , C5DN i =1 if respondent chooses “definitely no” in 4- or 5-alternative cases

The log-likelihood function for each model considered in this paper will be determined by the format of the relevant systematic utility-difference function, ΔV i; it is simply the sum of the relevant components that apply for each type of response format. The preference parameters to be estimated are embodied in this utility difference. The ordered logit threshold parameters, α mn and the differentials in the error dispersion, relative to the base case, are captured by the systematically varying parameter κ i:

Log L

$$ = {\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{N2} {{\left[ {C2Y_{i} 1n{\left( {P2Y_{i} } \right)} + C2N_{i} 1n{\left( {P2N_{i} } \right)}} \right]}} } \ldots {\text{ pairwise choices}} $$
$$ + {\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{N3} {{\left[ {C3Y_{i} 1n{\left( {P3Y_{i} } \right)} + C3M_{i} 1n{\left( {P3M_{i} } \right)} + C3N_{i} 1n{\left( {P3N_{i} } \right)}} \right]}} } \ldots {\text{three - alternative choices}} $$
$$ + {\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{N4} {{\left[ {C4DY_{i} 1n{\left( {P4DY_{i} } \right)} + C4PY_{i} 1n{\left( {P4PY_{i} } \right)} + C4PN_{i} 1n{\left( {P4PN_{i} } \right)} + C4PN_{i} 1n{\left( {P4DN_{i} } \right)}} \right]}} } \ldots {\text{four - alternative choices}} $$
$$ + {\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{N5} {{\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{C5DY_{i} 1n{\left( {P5DY_{i} } \right)} + C5PY_{i} 1n{\left( {P5PY_{i} } \right)} + C5M_{i} 1n{\left( {P5PM_{i} } \right)}}} \\ {{ + C5PN_{i} 1n{\left( {P5PN_{i} } \right)} + C5DN_{i} 1n{\left( {P5DN_{i} } \right)}}} \\ \end{array} } \right]}} } \ldots {\text{five - alternative choice}} $$

1.3 Optimization method

The unknown preference parameters (either as scalars, or as systematically varying parameters) are estimated by conventional maximum likelihood methods. Since the problem at hand is non-standard, however, the parameters cannot be estimated using packaged econometric software. We maximize the log-likelihood using MATLAB 7.1. We employ numeric derivatives and the BFGS algorithm, but recalculate the full Hessian matrix at the optimum using Greene’s formulas. Asymptotic t-test statistics are based on a symmetrized version of the Hessian, where the off-diagonal elements of the numeric Hessian, if different, are averaged.

Table 6 Incidental parameters

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Burghart, D.R., Cameron, T.A. & Gerdes, G.R. Valuing publicly sponsored research projects: Risks, scenario adjustments, and inattention. J Risk Uncertainty 35, 77–105 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-007-9018-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-007-9018-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation